Codex Ephraemi Rescriptus: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>Nodekeeper
m →‎Selected textual variants: Link to an internal page to help out the reader here
en>BartKamphuis
No edit summary
 
Line 1: Line 1:
The '''cobweb model''' or '''cobweb theory''' is an [[economic model]] that explains why [[price]]s might be subject to periodic fluctuations in certain types of [[market]]s. It describes cyclical [[supply and demand]] in a market where the amount [[Production, costs, and pricing|produced]] must be chosen before prices are observed. Producers' [[Expected value|expectation]]s about prices are assumed to be based on observations of previous prices. [[Nicholas Kaldor]] analyzed the model in 1934, coining the term 'cobweb theorem' (see Kaldor, 1938 and Pashigian, 2008), citing previous analyses in German by Henry Schultz and U. Ricci.
Hello and welcome. My title is Figures Wunder. Doing ceramics is what her family members and her enjoy. Years ago he moved to North Dakota and his family members enjoys it. Bookkeeping is my occupation.<br><br>my web-site: [http://www.mealsformoms.org/content/candida-tips-you-should-remember mealsformoms.org]
 
== The model ==
[[File:Cobweb theory (convergent).svg|thumb|The ''convergent'' case: each new outcome is successively closer to the intersection of supply and demand.]]
[[File:Cobweb theory (divergent).svg|thumb|The ''divergent'' case: each new outcome is successively further from the intersection of supply and demand.]]
The cobweb model is based on a time lag between supply and demand decisions. Agricultural markets are a context where the cobweb model might apply, since there is a lag between planting and [[harvest]]ing (Kaldor, 1934, p.&nbsp;133-134 gives two agricultural examples: rubber and corn). Suppose for example that as a result of unexpectedly bad weather, farmers go to market with an unusually small crop of strawberries. This shortage, equivalent to a leftward shift in the market's [[supply curve]], results in high prices. If farmers expect these high price conditions to continue, then in the following year, they will raise their production of strawberries relative to other crops. Therefore when they go to market the supply will be high, resulting in low prices. If they then expect low prices to continue, they will decrease their production of strawberries for the next year, resulting in high prices again.
 
This process is illustrated by the diagrams on the right. The [[equilibrium price]] is at the intersection of the supply and demand curves. A poor harvest in period 1 means supply falls to Q<sub>1</sub>, so that prices rise to P<sub>1</sub>. If producers plan their period 2 production under the expectation that this high price will continue, then the period 2 supply will be higher, at Q<sub>2</sub>. Prices therefore fall to P<sub>2</sub> when they try to sell all their output. As this process repeats itself, oscillating between periods of low supply with high prices and then high supply with low prices, the price and quantity trace out a spiral. They may spiral inwards, as in the top figure, in which case the economy converges to the equilibrium where supply and demand cross; or they may spiral outwards, with the fluctuations increasing in magnitude.
 
Simplifying, the cobweb model can have two main types of outcomes:
 
* If the supply curve is steeper than the demand curve, then the fluctuations decrease in magnitude with each cycle, so a plot of the prices and quantities over time would look like an inward spiral, as shown in the first diagram. This is called the stable or ''convergent case''.
* If the slope of the supply curve is less than the absolute value of the slope of the demand curve, then the fluctuations increase in magnitude with each cycle, so that prices and quantities spiral outwards. This is called the unstable or ''divergent case''.
 
Two other possibilities are:
* Fluctuations may also remain of constant magnitude, so a plot of the outcomes would produce a simple rectangle, if the supply and demand curves have exactly the same slope (in absolute value).
* If the supply curve is less steep than the demand curve near the point where the two curves cross, but more steep when we move sufficiently far away, then prices and quantities will spiral away from the equilibrium price but will not diverge indefinitely; instead, they may converge to a [[limit cycle]].
 
In either of the first two scenarios, the combination of the spiral and the supply and demand curves often looks like a [[Spider web|cobweb]], hence the name of the theory.
 
==Elasticities versus slopes==
The outcomes of the cobweb model are stated above in terms of slopes, but they are more commonly described in terms of elasticities. In terms of slopes, the ''convergent case'' requires that the slope of the supply curve be greater than the absolute value of the slope of the demand curve:
:<math>\frac{dP^S}{dQ^S} > \left|\frac{dP^D}{dQ^D}\right|.</math>
 
In standard terminology from microeconomics, define the ''[[Price elasticity of supply|elasticity of supply]]'' as <math>\frac{dQ^S/Q^S}{dP^S/P^S}</math>, and the ''[[Price elasticity of demand|elasticity of demand]]'' as <math>\frac{dQ^D/Q^D}{dP^D/P^D}</math>. If we evaluate these two elasticities at the equilibrium point, that is <math>P^S=P^D=P>0</math> and <math>Q^S=Q^D=Q>0</math>, then we see that the ''convergent case'' requires
:<math>\frac{dQ^S/Q}{dP^S/P}<\left|\frac{dQ^D/Q}{dP^D/P}\right|,</math>
whereas the ''divergent case'' requires
:<math>\frac{dQ^S/Q}{dP^S/P}>\left|\frac{dQ^D/Q}{dP^D/P}\right|.</math>
 
In words, the ''convergent case'' occurs when the demand curve is more elastic than the supply curve, at the equilibrium point. The ''divergent case'' occurs when the supply curve is more elastic than the demand curve, at the equilibrium point (see Kaldor, 1934, page 135, propositions (i) and (ii).)
 
== Role of expectations ==
One reason to be skeptical about this model's predictions is that it assumes producers are extremely shortsighted. Assuming that farmers look back at the most recent prices in order to forecast future prices might seem very reasonable, but this backward-looking forecasting (which is called [[adaptive expectations]]) turns out to be crucial for the model's fluctuations. When farmers expect high prices to continue, they produce too much and therefore end up with low prices, and vice versa.
 
In the stable case, this may not be an unbelievable outcome, since the farmers' prediction errors (the difference between the price they expect and the price that actually occurs) become smaller every period. In this case, after several periods prices and quantities will come close to the point where supply and demand cross, and predicted prices will be very close to actual prices. But in the unstable case, the farmers' errors get ''larger'' every period. This seems to indicate that [[adaptive expectations]] is a misleading assumption: how could farmers fail to notice that last period's price is ''not'' a good predictor of this period's price?
 
The fact that [[Agent (economics)|agents]] with adaptive expectations may make ever-increasing errors over time has led many economists to conclude that it is better to assume [[rational expectations]], that is, expectations consistent with the actual structure of the economy. However, the rational expectations assumption is controversial since it may exaggerate agents' understanding of the economy. The cobweb model serves as one of the best examples to illustrate why understanding [[Expectation (epistemic)|expectation]] formation is so important for understanding economic dynamics, and also why expectations are so controversial in recent economic theory.
 
==Evidence==
===Livestock herds===
 
The cobweb model has been interpreted as an explanation of fluctuations in various livestock markets, like those documented by Arthur Hanau in German hog markets; see [[Pork cycle]]. However, Rosen et al. (1994) proposed an alternative model which showed that because of the three-year life cycle of beef cattle, cattle populations would fluctuate over time even if ranchers had perfectly [[rational expectations]].<ref>Cf. [http://www.twincities.com/lotterman/ci_20293708/shipping-cattle-and-some-careers-cycles-play-out Twin Cities Pioneer Press, Edward Lotterman, 4. April 2012: Real World Economics: In shipping, cattle and some careers, cycles play out]</ref>
 
=== Human experimental data ===
 
In 1989, Wellford conducted twelve experimental sessions each conducted with five participants over thirty periods simulating the stable and unstable cases. Her results show that the unstable case did not result in the divergent behavior we see with cobweb expectations but rather the participants converged toward the rational expectations equilibrium. However, the price path variance in the unstable case was greater than that in the stable case (and the difference was shown to be statistically significant).
 
One way of interpreting these results is to say that in the long run, the participants behaved as if they had rational expectations, but that in the short run they made mistakes. These mistakes caused larger fluctuations in the unstable case than in the stable case.
 
== References ==
* W. Nicholson, ''Microeconomic Theory'', 7th ed., Ch. 17, pp.&nbsp;524–538. Dryden Press: ISBN 0-03-024474-9.
* J. Arifovic, 'Genetic Algorithm Learning and the Cobweb Model ', ''[[Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control]]'', vol. 18, Issue 1, (January 1994), 3-28.
* A. Hanau (1928), [http://www.diw.de/documents/dokumentenarchiv/17/43353/viertel_1928.pdf 'Die Prognose der Schweinepreise']. In: ''Vierteljahreshefte zur Konjunkturforschung'', Verlag Reimar Hobbing, Berlin.
* M. Ezekiel, 'The Cobweb Theorem', Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 52, No. 2 (February, 1938), pp.&nbsp;255–280.
* N. Kaldor, 'A Classificatory Note on the Determination of Equilibrium', ''[[Review of Economic Studies]]'', vol I (February, 1934), 122-36. (See especially pages 133-135.)
* M. Nerlove, 'Adaptive Expectations and Cobweb Phenomena', ''[[Quarterly Journal of Economics]]'', vol. lxxii (1958), 227-40.
* C.P. Wellford, 'A Laboratory Analysis of Price Dynamics and Expectations in the Cobweb Model', Discussion Paper 89-15 (University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ).
* J.F. Muth, 'Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements', ''[[Econometrica]]'', vol. 29 (1961), 315-35.
* B.P. Pashigian (2008), 'Cobweb theorem', ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'', 2nd edition.
* S. Rosen, K. Murphy, and J. Scheinkman, 'Cattle cycles', ''[[Journal of Political Economy]]'', vol. 102 (1994), pp.&nbsp;468–92.
* U. Ricci (1930), 'Die synthetische Ökonomie von Henry Ludwell Moore', ''[[Zeitschrift für Nationalökonomie]]'', page 649.
* H. Schultz, ''Der Sinn der statistischen Nachfragekurven'', page 34.
 
{{reflist}}
 
== See also ==
* [[General equilibrium]]
* [[Adaptive expectations]]
* [[Rational expectations]]
* [[Tatonnement]]
* [[Lotka–Volterra equation]]
* [[Cobweb plot]]
 
[[Category:Economic theories]]
[[Category:Economics models]]

Latest revision as of 09:48, 11 September 2014

Hello and welcome. My title is Figures Wunder. Doing ceramics is what her family members and her enjoy. Years ago he moved to North Dakota and his family members enjoys it. Bookkeeping is my occupation.

my web-site: mealsformoms.org