Rellich–Kondrachov theorem: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
en>Trappist the monk
m →‎Literature: Remove redundant |year= parameter from CS1 citations; using AWB
 
Line 1: Line 1:
A '''preferential attachment process''' is any of a class of processes in which some quantity, typically some form of wealth or credit, is distributed among a number of individuals or objects according to how much they already have, so that those who are already wealthy receive more than those who are not. "Preferential attachment" is only the most recent of many names that have been given to such processes.  They are also referred to under the names "Yule process", "cumulative advantage", "the rich get richer", and, less correctly, the "[[Matthew effect (sociology)|Matthew effect]]".  They are also related to [[Gibrat's law]]. The principal reason for scientific interest in preferential attachment is that it can, under suitable circumstances, generate [[power law]] distributions.
Friends contact him Royal. Alabama is exactly where he and his wife reside and he has every thing that he requirements there. One of the issues I love most is climbing and now I have time to take on new things. Managing individuals is what I do in my working day occupation.<br><br>Also visit my website: [http://Glskating.com/groups/great-ideas-about-auto-repair-that-you-can-use/ glskating.com]
 
==Definition==
A preferential attachment process is a [[stochastic process|stochastic]] [[urn problem|urn process]], meaning a process in which discrete units of wealth, usually called "balls", are added in a random or partly random fashion to a set of objects or containers, usually called "urns". A preferential attachment process is an urn process in which additional balls are added continuously to the system and are distributed among the urns as an increasing function of the number of balls the urns already have.  In the most commonly studied examples, the number of urns also increases continuously, although this is not a necessary condition for preferential attachment and examples have been studied with constant or even decreasing numbers of urns.
 
A classic example of a preferential attachment process is the growth in the number of [[species]] per [[genus]] in some higher [[taxon]] of biotic organisms.<ref name=YulePhilTrans>{{cite journal
  | last = Yule
  | first = G. U.
  | title = A Mathematical Theory of Evolution, based on the Conclusions of Dr. J. C. Willis, F.R.S
  | journal = [[Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B]]
  | volume = 213
  | pages = 21–87
  | year = 1925
  | doi = 10.1098/rstb.1925.0002
  | issue = 402–410
}}</ref>  New genera ("urns") are added to a taxon whenever a newly appearing species is considered sufficiently different from its predecessors that it does not belong in any of the current genera.  New species ("balls") are added as old ones [[speciation|speciate]] (i.e., split in two) and, assuming that new species belong to the same genus as their parent (except for those that start new genera), the probability that a new species is added to a genus will be proportional to the number of species the genus already has. This process, first studied by [[Udny Yule|Yule]], is a ''[[linear]]'' preferential attachment process, since the rate at which genera accrue new species is linear in the number they already have.
 
Linear preferential attachment processes in which the number of urns increases are known to produce a distribution of balls over the urns following the so-called [[Yule distribution]].  In the most general form of the process, balls are added to the system at an overall rate of ''m'' new balls for each new urn.  Each newly created urn starts out with ''k''<sub>0</sub> balls and further balls are added to urns at a rate proportional to the number ''k'' that they already have plus a constant ''a''&nbsp;>&nbsp;−''k''<sub>0</sub>.  With these definitions, the fraction ''P''(''k'') of urns having ''k'' balls in the limit of long time is given by<ref>{{cite journal
  | last = Newman
  | first = M. E. J.
  | title = Power laws, Pareto distributions and Zipf's law
  | journal = Contemporary Physics
  | volume = 46
  | pages = 323–351
  | year = 2005
  | arxiv = cond-mat/0412004
  | doi = 10.1080/00107510500052444
  | issue = 5
}}</ref>
 
:<math>
P(k) = {\mathrm{B}(k+a,\gamma)\over\mathrm{B}(k_0+a,\gamma-1)},
</math>
 
for ''k''&nbsp;≥&nbsp;''k''<sub>0</sub> (and zero otherwise), where B(''x'',&nbsp;''y'') is the Euler [[beta function]]:
 
:<math>
\mathrm{B}(x,y) = {\Gamma(x)\Gamma(y)\over\Gamma(x+y)},
</math>
 
with Γ(''x'') being the standard [[gamma function]], and
 
:<math>
\gamma = 2 + {k_0 + a\over m}.
</math>
 
The beta function behaves asymptotically as B(''x'',&nbsp;''y'')&nbsp;~&nbsp;''x''<sup>−''y''</sup> for large ''x'' and fixed ''y'', which implies that for large values of ''k'' we have
 
:<math>
P(k) \propto k^{-\gamma}.
</math>
 
In other words, the preferential attachment process generates a "long-tailed" distribution following a [[Pareto distribution]] or [[power law]] in its tail.  This is the primary reason for the historical interest in preferential attachment: the species distribution and many other phenomena are observed empirically to follow power laws and the preferential attachment process is a leading candidate mechanism to explain this behavior.  Preferential attachment is considered a possible candidate for, among other things, the distribution of the sizes of cities,<ref name=SimonBiomet>{{cite journal
  | last = Simon
  | first = H. A.
  | title = On a class of skew distribution functions
  | journal = Biometrika
  | volume = 42
  | pages = 425&ndash;440
  | year = 1955
  | doi=10.1093/biomet/42.3-4.425
  | issue = 3–4
}}</ref> the wealth of extremely wealthy individuals,<ref name=SimonBiomet /> the number of citations received by learned publications,<ref name=PriceJASIS>{{cite journal
  | last = Price
  | first = D. J. de S.
  | title = A general theory of bibliometric and other cumulative advantage processes
  | journal = J. Amer. Soc. Inform. Sci.
  | volume = 27
  | pages = 292&ndash;306
  | year = 1976
  | url = http://garfield.library.upenn.edu/price/pricetheory1976.pdf
  | doi = 10.1002/asi.4630270505
  | issue = 5
}}</ref> and the number of links to pages on the World Wide Web.<ref name=BAScience>{{cite journal
  | last = Barabási
  | first = A.-L.
  | coauthors = R. Albert
  | title = Emergence of scaling in random networks
  | journal = Science
  | volume = 286
  | pages = 509&ndash;512
  | year = 1999
  | arxiv = cond-mat/9910332
  | doi = 10.1126/science.286.5439.509
  | issue=5439
  | pmid=10521342
}}</ref>
 
The general model described here includes many other specific models as special cases.  In the species/genus example above, for instance, each genus starts out with a single species (''k''<sub>0</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;1) and gains new species in direct proportion to the number it already has (''a''&nbsp;=&nbsp;0), and hence ''P''(''k'')&nbsp;=&nbsp;B(''k'',&nbsp;''γ'')/B(''k''<sub>0</sub>,&nbsp;''γ''&nbsp;−&nbsp;1) with ''γ'' = 2&nbsp;+&nbsp;1/''m''.  Similarly the Price model for scientific citations<ref name=PriceJASIS /> corresponds to the case ''k''<sub>0</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;0, ''a''&nbsp; =&nbsp;1 and the widely studied [[Barabási-Albert model]]<ref name=BAScience /> corresponds to ''k''<sub>0</sub>&nbsp;=&nbsp;''m'', ''a''&nbsp;=&nbsp;0.
 
Preferential attachment is sometimes referred to as the [[Matthew effect]], but the two are not precisely equivalent.  The Matthew effect, first discussed by [[Robert Merton]],<ref>{{cite journal
  | last = Merton
  | first = Robert K.
  | title = The Matthew effect in science
  | journal = Science
  | volume = 159
  | pages = 56&ndash;63
  | year = 1968
  | doi = 10.1126/science.159.3810.56
  | pmid = 17737466
  | issue = 3810
}}</ref> is named for a passage in the [[bible|biblical]] [[Gospel of Matthew]]: "For everyone who has will be given more, and he will have an abundance. Whoever does not have, even what he has will be taken from him." ([[Gospel of Matthew|Matthew]] [[s:Bible (New International Version)/Matthew#25:29|25:29]], [[New International Version]].)  The preferential attachment process does not incorporate the taking away part. This point may be moot, however, since the scientific insight behind the Matthew effect is in any case entirely different.  Qualitatively it is intended to describe not a mechanical multiplicative effect like preferential attachment but a specific human behavior in which people are more likely to give credit to the famous than to the little known.  The classic example of the Matthew effect is a scientific discovery made simultaneously by two different people, one well known and the other little known.  It is claimed that under these circumstances people tend more often to credit the discovery to the well-known scientist.  Thus the real-world phenomenon the Matthew effect is intended to describe is quite distinct from (though certainly related to) preferential attachment.
 
==History==
The first rigorous consideration of preferential attachment seems to be that of [[Udny Yule|Yule]] in 1925, who used it to explain the power-law distribution of the number of species per genus of flowering plants.<ref name=YulePhilTrans />  The process is sometimes called a "Yule process" in his honor.  Yule was able to show that the process gave rise to a distribution with a power-law tail, but the details of his proof are, by today's standards, contorted and difficult, since the modern tools of stochastic process theory did not yet exist and he was forced to use more cumbersome methods of proof.
 
Most modern treatments of preferential attachment make use of the [[master equation]] method, whose use in this context was pioneered by [[Herbert A. Simon|Simon]] in 1955, in work on the distribution of sizes of cities and other phenomena.<ref name=SimonBiomet />
 
The first application of preferential attachment to learned citations was given by [[Derek J. de Solla Price|Price]] in 1976.<ref name=PriceJASIS />  (He referred to the process as a "cumulative advantage" process.)  His was also the first application of the process to the growth of a network, producing what would now be called a [[scale-free network]].  It is in the context of network growth that the process is most frequently studied today.  Price also promoted preferential attachment as a possible explanation for power laws in many other phenomena, including [[Lotka's law]] of scientific productivity and [[Bradford's law]] of journal use.
 
The application of preferential attachment to the growth of the World Wide Web was proposed by [[BA model|Barabási and Albert]] in 1999.<ref name=BAScience />  Barabási and Albert also coined the name "preferential attachment" by which the process is best known today and suggested that the process might apply to the growth of other networks as well.
 
==See also==
{{colbegin}}
* [[Assortative mixing]]
* [[Stochastic processes]]
* [[Power law]]
* [[Yule–Simon distribution]]
* [[Simon model]]
* [[Complex network]]
* [[BA model]]
* [[Chinese restaurant process]]
* [[Bose–Einstein condensation: a network theory approach]]
* [[Double jeopardy (marketing)]]
* [[Capital accumulation]]
* [[Wealth condensation]]
* [[The rich get richer (statistics)]]
* [[Matthew effect (sociology)]]
* [[Bibliogram]]
{{colend}}
 
==References==
<references/>
 
{{DEFAULTSORT:Preferential Attachment}}
[[Category:Stochastic processes]]

Latest revision as of 22:41, 25 December 2014

Friends contact him Royal. Alabama is exactly where he and his wife reside and he has every thing that he requirements there. One of the issues I love most is climbing and now I have time to take on new things. Managing individuals is what I do in my working day occupation.

Also visit my website: glskating.com