Bernoulli's principle: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>ClueBot NG
m Reverting possible vandalism by 1.23.124.46 to version by JYBot. False positive? Report it. Thanks, ClueBot NG. (1187849) (Bot)
 
en>Jack Greenmaven
m Reverted 1 edit by 117.212.82.193 identified as test/vandalism using STiki
Line 1: Line 1:
== 青衣老人の中 ==
[[File:GDP (PPP) per capita by countries.png|thumb|400px|GDP per capita by countries in 2013, calculated using PPP exchange rates<ref>Based on figures from CIA world factbook</ref>]]
In [[economics]], '''purchasing power parity''' ('''PPP''') is a component of some [[Economic theory|economic theories]] and is a technique used to determine the relative [[value (economics)|value]] of different [[currency|currencies]].


今怒りで覆われて [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-8.html casio 腕時計 スタンダード]。<br>青衣老人の中<br>'!ナンセンス」商工会議所は、「色」が沈没した直面し、言った:'今日の家族は何が起こるか、あなたは知らないか、曹操は、5つのファミリーの一つであり、私は良い試合になるようにすると、家を出るが起こった、そして曹操シャンは精錬「医学」ウィザードだけでなく、彼と結婚あなたが良い家を見つけるために免除がトップ5葉ホーム家族の危機を中退しているが、またのために作るためのまれなケースである。 [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-11.html 腕時計 メンズ casio] '<br><br>「でも、本当に、私は曹操シャンと結婚しましょう​​、私たちはそれが危機を解決できることだと思いますか?曹操は不吉な、私は長い間浸食に思っている、家を出るようにすることは、しかし、Yangruhukouにある! [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-10.html カシオの時計] '青女怒って。<br>それは青衣老人の遅れの名前だったので、彼女の言葉を<br>、直ちにチェンシェンは言った: [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-11.html カシオ腕時計 g-shock] 'これはありません、あなたが行う方法で私に話すことができるあなたを救うためにカナンどのお口の中で家ではない天才ということです?他の人が高すぎるに見えた、私の危機はしていないさりげなく家を、葉
Theories that invoke purchasing power parity assume that in some circumstances (for example, as a long-run tendency) it would cost exactly the same number of, say, [[US dollar]]s to buy [[euro]]s and then to use the proceeds to buy a market basket of goods as it would cost to use those dollars directly in purchasing the market basket of goods.
相关的主题文章:
<ul>
 
  <li>[http://bbs.tuizdm.com/home.php?mod=space&uid=80658 http://bbs.tuizdm.com/home.php?mod=space&uid=80658]</li>
 
  <li>[http://birdsongresort.com/guestbook2/guestbook.cgi http://birdsongresort.com/guestbook2/guestbook.cgi]</li>
 
  <li>[http://cyjgmr.com/plus/feedback.php?aid=6 http://cyjgmr.com/plus/feedback.php?aid=6]</li>
 
</ul>


== すべてのスコアは、すべてのブレーク後、意志、 ==
The concept of purchasing power parity allows one to estimate what the [[exchange rate]] between two currencies would have to be in order for the exchange to be on par with the [[purchasing power]] of the two countries' currencies. Using that PPP rate for hypothetical currency conversions, a given amount of one currency thus has the same purchasing power whether used directly to purchase a market basket of goods or used to convert at the PPP rate to the other currency and then purchase the market basket using that currency. Observed deviations of the exchange rate from purchasing power parity are measured by deviations of the [[real exchange rate]] from its PPP value of 1.


日によって所有ガマ帝国は、あまりにも、したくない [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-0.html カシオ 時計 価格]<br>すべてのスコアは、すべてのブレーク後、意志、<br> [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-8.html casio 腕時計 スタンダード]!<br>目を覚まし古い<br>第六百三十一章の薬 [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-11.html casio 腕時計 メンズ]!<br><br>第六百三十一章「医療」目を覚まし古い [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-4.html カシオ 電波ソーラー時計]!<br>そのような壮大なそびえ立つかみそり·ストレート [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-9.html カシオ 掛け時計] 'プラグ'空、緑豊かな森林など<br>、山、。<br><br>どこか険しい崖側との間の山の中で、穿く岩の上に張り出し、、の存在下で、目を閉じて、あぐらをかいて座っている若い黒人のローブは、巨大な深紅の「医学」丁の像を置いた、三脚内の「医学」、緑の炎の上昇、よく見ると、それは漠然と炎、実際にゆっくりと忍び寄るにおける「液体」ボディ美しい「色」の質量を持っていることを見てすることができます。<br>焼き炎の下では、常にバブル崩壊、このグループ「流体」は体の体積が僅かになりますときはいつでも、体の表面に豪華な「液体」小さな気泡を<br>投げ
PPP exchange rates help to avoid misleading international comparisons that can arise with the use of market exchange rates. For example, suppose that two countries produce the same physical amounts of goods as each other in each of two different years. Since market exchange rates fluctuate substantially, when the GDP of one country measured in its own currency is converted to the other country's currency using market exchange rates, one country might be inferred to have higher [[real GDP]] than the other country in one year but lower in the other; both of these inferences would fail to reflect the reality of their relative levels of production. But if one country's GDP is converted into the other country's currency using PPP exchange rates instead of observed market exchange rates, the false inference will not occur.
相关的主题文章:
<ul>
 
  <li>[http://www.klt365.com/plus/feedback.php?aid=407 http://www.klt365.com/plus/feedback.php?aid=407]</li>
 
  <li>[http://bbs.ibmaix.cn/home.php?mod=space&uid=22252 http://bbs.ibmaix.cn/home.php?mod=space&uid=22252]</li>
 
  <li>[http://rebuild.digitalexcellence.net/index.php?title=User:Zoybozgtmvgp#.E3.80.8C.E6.82.AA.E9.AD.94.E3.81.AE.E6.97.A5.E3.83.95.E3.82.A7.E3.83.8B.E3.83.83.E3.82.AF.E3.82.B9 http://rebuild.digitalexcellence.net/index.php?title=User:Zoybozgtmvgp#.E3.80.8C.E6.82.AA.E9.AD.94.E3.81.AE.E6.97.A5.E3.83.95.E3.82.A7.E3.83.8B.E3.83.83.E3.82.AF.E3.82.B9]</li>
 
</ul>


== シャオヤンこのパフォーマンス、どのように「色」 ==
== Concept ==


、次回はあなたがあまり「医学」材料の一部を破壊することができるはずです。 [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-1.html カシオ スタンダード 腕時計] '<br><br>は頭、シャオヤン慎重ダンは良いパルスを受信して​​から、再び引き戻さ一枚ダンは空気を飲み込む、体内執念深い応答を待って、彼の目を閉じたガードうなずいた [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-13.html カシオ アナログ 腕時計]。<br>半時間<br>た後、シャオヤンがゆっくりと目を開け、この時間は、彼が、三脚の前に「医学」、深呼吸してから、彼の手を伸ばし、錬金術を見て、再びトップフォームに戻ってきた再び始まる [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-0.html カシオ 腕時計 チタン]...<br><br>古い [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-5.html カシオ 腕時計 スタンダード] '薬'精錬成功Humaiダン先例、精錬ビングダンと、言ったように、それは開始時を除いて、非常に滑らかで所望の材料、シャオヤンの達成の「薬」とは、異なるレベルのため、少しぎくしゃくまた、ほとんどの背後に痛烈な一連の工程を、一般的に滑らかで、錬金術は、あっても非常にうるさい [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-3.html カシオ 電波時計 腕時計] '薬'古いが、非常に満足していることがわかる。シャオヤンこのパフォーマンス、どのように「色」
The idea originated with the [[School of Salamanca]] in the 16th century and was developed in its modern form by [[Gustav Cassel]] in 1918.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Cassel|first=Gustav|date=December 1918|title=Abnormal Deviations in International Exchanges|publisher=The Economic Journal|volume= 28, No. 112|issue=112|pages=413–415|jstor=2223329}}</ref><ref name=princetonenc>{{cite encyclopedia |last=Cheung |first=Yin-Wong|editor-last=Reinert|editor-first=Kenneth A.|editor2-last=Rajan |editor2-first=Ramkishen S.|editor3-last=Glass|editor3-first=Amy Jocelyn|editor4-first=Lewis S. |editor4-last=Davis|title=purchasing power parity|encyclopedia=The Princeton Encyclopedia of the World Economy|url=http://books.google.com/books?id=BnEDno1hTegC&pg=PA942|accessdate=2 October 2011|volume=I|year=2009|publisher=Princeton University Press |location=Princeton |isbn=978-0-691-12812-2 |page=942}}</ref>
相关的主题文章:
The concept is based on the [[law of one price]], where in the absence of [[transaction cost]]s and official [[trade barrier]]s, identical goods will have the same price in different markets when the prices are expressed in the same currency.<ref name=Krugman>{{cite book|last=Krugman and Obstfeld|title=International Economics|year=2009|publisher=Pearson Education, Inc.}}</ref>
<ul>
 
  <li>[http://www.mj-wg.com/forum.php?mod=viewthread&tid=34801 http://www.mj-wg.com/forum.php?mod=viewthread&tid=34801]</li>
 
  <li>[http://clar.ntzx.cn/uhome/space.php?uid=129697&do=blog&id=3033139 http://clar.ntzx.cn/uhome/space.php?uid=129697&do=blog&id=3033139]</li>
 
  <li>[http://www.67cavaliers.com/cgi-bin/guestbook.cgi http://www.67cavaliers.com/cgi-bin/guestbook.cgi]</li>
 
</ul>


== シャオヤン、曹操の正面から見 ==
Another interpretation is that the difference in the rate of change in prices at home and abroad—the difference in the inflation rates—is equal to the percentage depreciation or appreciation of the exchange rate.


人今日は奪うように持っていることを意味? [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-5.html 時計 casio] 「シャオヤンの足音がゆっくりと一歩を踏み出す、そっと笑った。<br>シャオヤンのため<br>は曹操シャンもわずかにこれらの年の彼の才能の錬金術に目を細め、少しいじめっ子勢いだったが、めったに人の若い世代は、そのように処理されていない [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-9.html カシオ 腕時計 チタン]。<br>シャオヤン、曹操の正面から見<br>はわずかな後退ではなく、ストレートシャオヤンを見つめて一歩前進、とシャオヤン間の間隔が、Chixu短い距離、彼の目を持っていなかったシングルだけでなく、言った: [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-2.html カシオの時計] 'シャオヤン私はあなたにもあなたがプレイしている知っていると聞きましたが、あなたはあなたにも頭痛の非常に恐れて感じていても、限り私は曹操Fangchuhualaiとして、氷河の谷、私曹操をしない知っている必要があります。 [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-3.html カシオ gps 時計] '<br><br>はシャオヤンの指がゆっくりと広がり、「私も人を殺すことができなかった、あなたがあなたの曹操思いますか、家の魂よりも対処がより困難になりますか?家の魂 [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-15.html カシオ 腕時計 激安] 'は、退屈な道が鳴ります。<br>これはわずかに変化を聞いた、曹操片面「色」<br>
Deviations from parity imply differences in purchasing power of a "basket of goods" across countries, which means that for the purposes of many international comparisons, countries' GDPs or other national income statistics need to be "PPP-adjusted" and converted into common units. The best-known purchasing power adjustment is the [[Geary–Khamis dollar]] (the "international dollar"). The [[Exchange rate#Nominal and real exchange rates|real exchange rate]] is then equal to the nominal exchange rate, adjusted for differences in price levels. If purchasing power parity held exactly, then the real exchange rate would always equal one. However, in practice the real exchange rates exhibit both short run and long run deviations from this value, for example due to reasons illuminated in the [[Balassa–Samuelson theorem]].
相关的主题文章:
<ul>
 
  <li>[http://www.lolsex.info/forum.php?mod=viewthread&tid=53654 http://www.lolsex.info/forum.php?mod=viewthread&tid=53654]</li>
 
  <li>[http://www.acoh-re.jp/post_mail/postmail.cgi http://www.acoh-re.jp/post_mail/postmail.cgi]</li>
 
  <li>[http://www.islanddecorators.com/cgi-bin/decor/guestbook.cgi http://www.islanddecorators.com/cgi-bin/decor/guestbook.cgi]</li>
 
</ul>


== 3538 ==
There can be marked differences between purchasing power adjusted incomes and those converted via market exchange rates.<ref>[http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/36a2d566-ad82-11dc-9386-0000779fd2ac.html FT.com / World - China, India economies ‘40% smaller’:By Scheherazade Daneshkhu in London Published: December 18 2007 18:04]</ref> For example, the [[World Bank|World Bank's]] ''World Development Indicators 2005'' estimated that in 2003, one [[Geary-Khamis dollar]] was equivalent to about 1.8 [[Renminbi|Chinese yuan]] by purchasing power parity<ref>[http://devdata.worldbank.org/wdi2005/Table5_7.htm 2005 World Development Indicators: Table 5.7 | Relative prices and exchange rates]</ref>—considerably different from the nominal exchange rate. This discrepancy has large implications; for instance, when converted via the nominal exchange rates [[List of countries by GDP (nominal) per capita|GDP per capita]] in [[India]] is about [[United States dollar|US$]]1,704<ref>[[List of countries by past and future GDP (nominal)]]</ref> while on a PPP basis it is about US$3,608.<ref>[[List of countries by future GDP (PPP) per capita estimates]]</ref> At the other extreme, [[Denmark|Denmark's]] nominal GDP per capita is around US$62,100, but its PPP figure is US$37,304.


Nalan傑は彼を保護するので、コミットブランド薬を取り除くために、彼らはすべての後、あまりにも驚くことはありません十分なだけとシャオヤン·テンマイテルであることができる他の人の手に自分の命のピンチは、山の近くで会ったが、杭はためらうことなく、まだとても重いです下では、これは彼らが人々を理解していなかったことにやや驚いている [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-9.html カシオ 時計 プロトレック]<br>あなたが知っているhuan​​hangrn、戦争の背後にある木が、全体の木造住宅、ああ、彼らの力は、ああ、少数の家族をBimiteerが、しなかったかの光の量結局強い競争、多くのマイテルファミリーよりもさらに木造の家、マイテルファミリは、家業である戦士ファミリー木造住宅のようなものではありません [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-2.html 腕時計 casio]<br><br>もちろん、強いありますが、最終力のではなく、このようなことは、このレベルの後、ちょうど発生しやすい戦士の精神に頼って、さらにはない、山マイテルテンパワーの先頭ですまたは才能の育成に応じて、この時点では、2タッチの間に大きな差はありません [http://www.ispsc.edu.ph/nav/japandi/casio-rakuten-1.html カシオ 時計 メンズ]
==Functions==
相关的主题文章:
The purchasing power parity exchange rate serves two main functions. PPP exchange rates can be useful for making comparisons between countries because they stay fairly constant from day to day or week to week and only change modestly, if at all, from year to year. Second, over a period of years, exchange rates do tend to move in the general direction of the PPP exchange rate and there is some value to knowing in which direction the exchange rate is more likely to shift over the long run.
<ul>
 
 
Among other uses, PPP rates facilitate international comparisons of [[income]], as market exchange rates are often volatile, being affected by political and financial factors that do not lead to immediate changes in income and tend to systematically understate the standard of living in poor countries, due to the [[Balassa–Samuelson effect]].
  <li>[http://www.boysof78.net/cgi-bin/gbook/guestbook.cgi http://www.boysof78.net/cgi-bin/gbook/guestbook.cgi]</li>
 
 
==Measurement==
  <li>[http://www.ziewang.com/forum.php?mod=viewthread&tid=1713040 http://www.ziewang.com/forum.php?mod=viewthread&tid=1713040]</li>
The PPP exchange-rate calculation is controversial because of the difficulties of finding comparable [[Market basket|baskets of goods]] to compare purchasing power across countries.{{Citation needed|date=April 2012}}
 
 
  <li>[http://www.bowchina.org/home.php?mod=space&uid=163696 http://www.bowchina.org/home.php?mod=space&uid=163696]</li>
Estimation of purchasing power parity is complicated by the fact that countries do not simply differ in a uniform [[price level]]; rather, the difference in food prices may be greater than the difference in housing prices, while also less than the difference in entertainment prices. People in different countries typically consume different baskets of goods. It is necessary to compare the cost of baskets of goods and services using a [[price index]]. This is a difficult task because purchasing patterns and even the goods available to purchase differ across countries.
 
 
</ul>
Thus, it is necessary to make adjustments for differences in the quality of goods and services. Furthermore, the basket of goods representative of one economy will vary from that of another: Americans eat more bread; Chinese more rice. Hence a PPP calculated using the US consumption as a base will differ from that calculated using China as a base. Additional statistical difficulties arise with multilateral comparisons when (as is usually the case) more than two countries are to be compared.
 
Various ways of averaging bilateral PPPs can provide a more stable multilateral comparison, but at the cost of distorting bilateral ones. These are all general issues of indexing; as with other [[price index|price indices]] there is no way to reduce complexity to a single number that is equally satisfying for all purposes. Nevertheless, PPPs are typically robust in the face of the many problems that arise in using market exchange rates to make comparisons.
 
For example, in 2005 the price of a gallon of gasoline in Saudi Arabia was USD 0.91, and in Norway the price was USD 6.27.<ref>[http://money.cnn.com/pf/features/lists/global_gasprices/ "Global Gas Prices," (March 2005)] [http://money.cnn.com CNN Money]. Accessed June 2011.</ref> The significant differences in price wouldn't contribute to accuracy in a PPP analysis, despite all of the variables that contribute to the significant differences in price. More comparisons have to be made and used as variables in the overall formulation of the PPP.
 
When PPP comparisons are to be made over some interval of time, proper account needs to be made of [[inflation]]ary effects.
 
===Law of one price===
Although it may seem as if PPPs and the [[law of one price]] are the same, there is a difference: the law of one price applies to individual commodities whereas PPP applies to the general price level. If the law of one price is true for all commodities then PPP is also therefore true; however, when discussing the validity of PPP, some argue that the law of one price does not need to be true exactly for PPP to be valid. If the law of one price is not true for a certain commodity, the price levels will not differ enough from the level predicted by PPP.<ref name="Krugman"/>
 
The purchasing power parity theory states that the exchange rate between one currency and another currency is in equlibirium when their domestic purchasing powers at that rate of exchange are equivalent.
 
===Big Mac Index===
[[Image:McDonald's BigMac ja-3.jpg|thumb|right|[[Big Mac]] hamburgers, like this one from [[Japan]], are similar worldwide.]]
{{Main|Big Mac Index}}
An example of one measure of the [[law of one price]], which underlies purchasing power parity, is the [[Big Mac Index]], popularized by ''[[The Economist]]'', which compares the prices of a [[Big Mac]] burger in [[McDonald's Corporation|McDonald's]] restaurants in different countries.  The Big Mac Index is presumably useful because although it is based on a single consumer product that may not be typical, it is a relatively standardized product that includes input costs from a wide range of sectors in the local economy, such as agricultural commodities (beef, bread, lettuce, cheese), labor (blue and white collar), advertising, rent and real estate costs, transportation, etc.
 
In theory, the law of one price would hold that if, to take an example, the Canadian dollar were to be significantly overvalued relative to the U.S. dollar according to the Big Mac Index, that gap should be unsustainable because Canadians would import their Big Macs from or travel to the U.S. to consume them, thus putting upward demand pressure on the U.S. dollar by virtue of Canadians buying the U.S. dollars needed to purchase the U.S.-made Big Macs and simultaneously placing downward supply pressure on the Canadian dollar by virtue of Canadians selling their currency in order to buy those same U.S. dollars.
 
The alternative to this exchange rate adjustment would be an adjustment in prices, with Canadian McDonald's stores compelled to lower prices to remain competitive.  Either way, the valuation difference should be reduced assuming [[perfect competition]] and a perfectly [[Tradability|tradable good]].  In practice, of course, the Big Mac is not a perfectly tradable good and there may also be capital flows that sustain relative demand for the Canadian dollar. The difference in price may have its origins in a variety of factors besides direct input costs such as government regulations and [[product differentiation]].<ref name="Krugman"/>
 
In some emerging economies, western fast food represents an expensive niche product price well above the price of traditional staples—i.e. the Big Mac is not a mainstream 'cheap' meal as it is in the West, but a luxury import. This relates back to the idea of product differentiation: the fact that few [[substitute good|substitutes]] for the Big Mac are available confers [[market power]] on McDonald's.  Additionally, with countries like Argentina that have abundant beef resources, consumer prices in general may not be as cheap as implied by the price of a Big Mac.
 
The following table, based on data from ''The Economist'''s January 2013 calculations, shows the under (−) and over (+) valuation of the local currency against the U.S. dollar in %, according to the Big Mac index.  To take an example calculation, the local price of a Big Mac in Hong Kong when converted to U.S. dollars at the market exchange rate was $2.19, or 50% of the local price for a Big Mac in the U.S. of $4.37.  Hence the Hong Kong dollar was deemed to be 50% undervalued relative to the U.S. dollar on a PPP basis.
 
{| class="sortable wikitable"
|-
! Country !! Price level (% relative to the US)<ref>[http://www.economist.com/content/big-mac-index] ''[[The Economist]]'' January 2013</ref>
|-
| Argentina || −13
|-
| Australia || +12
|-
| Austria || +5
|-
| Belgium || +18
|-
| Brazil || +29
|-
| Canada || +24
|-
| Chile || 0
|-
| China || −41
|-
| Colombia || +11
|-
| Costa Rica || +1
|-
| Czech Republic || −15
|-
| Estonia || −16
|-
| Denmark || +19
|-
| Egypt || −45
|-
| Euro area || +12
|-
| Finland || +17
|-
| France || +12
|-
| Germany || +13
|-
| Greece || +3
|-
| Hong Kong || −50
|-
| Hungary || −13
|-
| India || −63
|-
| Indonesia || −35
|-
| Ireland || +8
|-
| Israel || −8
|-
| Italy || +20
|-
| Japan || −20
|-
| Latvia || −25
|-
| Lithuania || −30
|-
| Malaysia || −41
|-
| Mexico || −34
|-
| Netherlands || +7
|-
| New Zealand || −1
|-
| Norway || +80
|-
| Pakistan || −32
|-
| Peru || −11
|-
| Philippines || −33
|-
| Poland || −33
|-
| Portugal || −8
|-
| Russia || −45
|-
| Saudi Arabia || −33
|-
| Singapore || −17
|-
| South Africa || −54
|-
| South Korea || −22
|-
| Spain || +9
|-
| Sri Lanka || −37
|-
| Sweden || +75
|-
| Switzerland || +63
|-
| Taiwan || −42
|-
| Thailand || −33
|-
| Turkey || +10
|-
| UAE || −25
|-
| Ukraine || −47
|-
| United Kingdom || −3
|-
| United States || 0
|-
| Uruguay || +25
|-
| Venezuela || +108
|}
 
===iPad Index===
Like the [[Big Mac Index]], the iPad index (elaborated by [[Commonwealth Securities | ComSec]]) compares an item's price in various locations.  Unlike the Big Mac, however, each iPad is produced in the same place and all iPads (within the same model) have identical performance characteristics.  Price differences are therefore a function of transportation costs, taxes, and to a lesser extent, the prices that may be realized in individual markets.  It is worth noting that an iPad will cost about twice as much in Argentina as in the United States.
 
{| class="sortable wikitable"
|-
! Country !! Price (US Dollars)<ref>[http://www.theage.com.au/business/markets/is-the-aussie-too-expensive-ipad-index-says-no-20130923-2u9jj.html] ''The Age'' 23 September 2013</ref><ref>[http://www.comsec.com.au/redir.asp?ID=media2] ''23rd Sep 2013, CommSec Economic Insight: CommSec iPad Index'' Sep 23,2013 </ref><ref>[https://www.comsec.com.au/] ''[[Commonwealth Securities]]'' 23 September 2013</ref><ref>[https://www.businessinsider.com./] ''[[How much an iPad costs]]'' 21 December 2013</ref>
 
|-
| Argentina || $1,094.11
|-
| Australia || $506.66
|-
| Austria || $674.96
|-
| Belgium || $618.34
|-
| Brazil || $791.40
|-
| Brunei || $525.52
|-
| Canada (Montréal) || $557.18
|-
| Canada (no tax) || $484.61
|-
| Chile || $602.13
|-
| China || $602.52
|-
| Czech Republic || $676.69
|-
| Denmark || $725.32
|-
| Finland || $695.25
|-
| France || $688.49
|-
| Germany || $618.34
|-
| Greece || $715.54
|-
| Hong Kong || $501.52
|-
| Hungary || $679.64
|-
| India || $512.61
|-
| Ireland || $630.73
|-
| Italy || $674.96
|-
| Japan || $501.56
|-
| Luxembourg || $641.50
|-
| Malaysia || $473.77
|-
| Mexico || $591.62
|-
| Netherlands || $683.08
|-
| New Zealand || $610.45
|-
| Norway || $655.92
|-
| Philippines || $556.42
|-
| Poland || $704.51
|-
| Portugal || $688.49
|-
| Russia || $596.08
|-
| Singapore || $525.98
|-
| Slovakia || $674.96
|-
| Slovenia || $674.96
|-
| South Africa || $559.38
|-
| South Korea || $576.20
|-
| Spain || $674.96
|-
| Sweden || $706.87
|-
| Switzerland || $617.58
|-
| Taiwan || $538.34
|-
| Thailand || $530.72
|-
| Turkey || $656.96
|-
| UAE || $544.32
|-
| United Kingdom || $638.81
|-
| US (California) || $546.91
|-
| US (no tax) || $499.00
|-
| Viêtnam || $554.08
|-
|}
 
===OECD comparative price levels===
Each month, the [[Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development]] measures the difference in price levels between its member countries by calculating the ratios of PPPs for [[household final consumption expenditure|private final consumption expenditure]] to exchange rates. The OECD table below indicates the number of US dollars needed, as of January 2014, in each of the countries listed to buy the same representative basket of consumer goods and services that would cost 100 USD in the United States.
 
According to the table, an American living or travelling in Switzerland on an income denominated in US dollars would find that country (in January 2014) to be the most expensive of the group, having to spend 69% more US dollars to maintain a standard of living comparable to the USA in terms of [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]]. 
 
{| class="sortable wikitable"
|-
! Country !! Price level (USA = 100)<ref>[http://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=CPL] ''[[OECD]]'' July 4, 2013</ref>
|-
| Australia || 145
|-
| Austria || 116
|-
| Belgium || 119
|-
| Canada || 121
|-
| Chile || 73
|-
| Czech Republic || 75
|-
| Denmark || 154
|-
| Estonia || 84
|-
| Finland || 133
|-
| France || 118
|-
| Germany || 111
|-
| Greece || 98
|-
| Hungary || 65
|-
| Iceland || 122
|-
| Ireland || 126
|-
| Israel || 121
|-
| Italy || 112
|-
| Japan || 113
|-
| Korea || 86
|-
| Luxembourg || 135
|-
| Mexico || 72
|-
| Netherlands || 119
|-
| New Zealand || 130
|-
| Norway || 161
|-
| Poland || 63
|-
| Portugal || 94
|-
| Slovakia || 77
|-
| Slovenia || 93
|-
| Spain || 106
|-
| Sweden || 135
|-
| Switzerland || 169
|-
| Turkey || 67
|-
| United Kingdom || 125
|-
| United States || 100
|}
 
===Measurement issues===
 
In addition to methodological issues presented by the selection of a basket of goods, PPP estimates can also vary based on the statistical capacity of participating countries. The [[International Comparison Program]], which PPP estimates are based on, require the disaggregation of national accounts into production, expenditure or (in some cases) income, and not all participating countries routinely disaggregate their data into such categories.
Some aspects of PPP comparison are theoretically impossible or unclear. For example, there is no basis for comparison between the Ethiopian laborer who lives on teff with the Thai laborer who lives on rice, because teff is not commercially available in Thailand and rice is not in Ethiopia, so the price of rice in Ethiopia or teff in Thailand cannot be determined. As a general rule, the more similar the price structure between countries, the more valid the PPP comparison.
PPP levels will also vary based on the formula used to calculate price matrices. Different possible formulas include GEKS-Fisher, Geary-Khamis, IDB, and the superlative method. Each has advantages and disadvantages.
Linking regions presents another methodological difficulty. In the 2005 ICP round, regions were compared by using a list of some 1,000 identical items for which a price could be found for 18 countries, selected so that at least two countries would be in each region. While this was superior to earlier "bridging" methods, which do not fully take into account differing quality between goods, it may serve to overstate the PPP basis of poorer countries, because the price indexing on which PPP is based will assign to poorer countries the greater weight of goods consumed in greater shares in richer countries.
 
==Need for adjustments to GDP==
{{multiple image
| align = right
| width = 400
| direction = vertical
}}
 
The exchange rate reflects transaction values for [[tradable goods|traded goods]] ''between'' countries in contrast to non-traded goods, that is, goods produced for home-country use. Also, currencies are traded for purposes other than trade in goods and services, ''e.g.'', to buy [[capital asset]]s whose prices vary more than those of physical goods. Also, different [[interest rate]]s, [[speculation]], [[Hedge (finance)|hedging]] or interventions by [[central bank]]s can influence the [[foreign exchange market|foreign-exchange market]].
 
The PPP method is used as an alternative to correct for possible statistical bias. The [[Penn World Table]] is a widely cited source of PPP adjustments, and the so-called [[Penn effect]] reflects such a systematic bias in using exchange rates to outputs among countries.
 
For example, if the value of the [[Mexican peso]] falls by half compared to the [[US dollar]], the Mexican [[Gross Domestic Product]] measured in dollars will also halve. However, this exchange rate results from international trade and financial markets. It does not necessarily mean that Mexicans are poorer by a half; if incomes and prices measured in pesos stay the same, they will be no worse off assuming that imported goods are not essential to the quality of life of individuals. Measuring income in different countries using PPP exchange rates helps to avoid this problem.
PPP exchange rates are especially useful when official exchange rates are artificially manipulated by governments. Countries with strong government control of the economy sometimes enforce official exchange rates that make their own currency artificially strong. By contrast, the currency's black market exchange rate is artificially weak. In such cases, a PPP exchange rate is likely the most realistic basis for economic comparison.
 
===Updating PPP rates for GDP===
 
Since global PPP estimates —such as those provided by the ICP— are not calculated annually, but for a single year, PPP exchange rates for years other than the benchmark year need to be updated. This is done using the country's [[GDP deflator]]. To calculate a country's PPP exchange rate in [[Geary–Khamis dollar]]s for a particular year, the calculation proceeds in the following manner:
<math>\textrm{PPPrate}_{X,i}=\frac{\textrm{PPPrate}_{X,b}\cdot \frac{\textrm{GDPdef}_{X,i}}{\textrm{GDPdef}_{X,b}}}{\textrm{PPPrate}_{U,b}\cdot \frac{\textrm{GDPdef}_{U,i}}{\textrm{GDPdef}_{U,b}}}</math>
Where PPPrate<sub>X,i</sub> is the PPP exchange rate of country X for year i, PPPrate<sub>X,b</sub> is the PPP exchange rate of country X for the benchmark year, PPPrate<sub>U,b</sub> is the PPP exchange rate of the [[United States]] (US) for the benchmark year (equal to 1), GDPdef<sub>X,i</sub> is the GDP deflator of country X for year i, GDPdef<sub>X,b</sub> is the GDP deflator of country X for the benchmark year, GDPdef<sub>U,i</sub> is the GDP deflator of the US for year i, and GDPdef<sub>U,b</sub> is the GDP deflator of the US for the benchmark year.
 
==Difficulties==
There are a number of reasons that different measures do not perfectly reflect standards of living.
 
===Range and quality of goods===
The goods that the currency has the "power" to purchase are a basket of goods of different types:
# Local, non-tradable goods and services (like electric power) that are produced and sold domestically.
# Tradable goods such as non-perishable [[commodities]] that can be sold on the international market (like [[diamond]]s).
 
The more that a product falls into category 1, the more that its price will be from the currency [[exchange rate]], moving towards the PPP exchange rate. Conversely, category 2 products tend to trade close to the currency exchange rate. (See also [[Penn effect]]).
 
More processed and expensive products are likely to be [[tradable]], falling into the second category, and drifting from the PPP exchange rate to the currency exchange rate. Even if the PPP "value" of the Ethiopian currency is three times stronger than the currency exchange rate, it won't buy three times as much of internationally traded goods like steel, cars and microchips, but non-traded goods like housing, services ("haircuts"), and domestically produced crops. The relative price differential between tradables and non-tradables from high-income to low-income countries is a consequence of the [[Balassa–Samuelson effect]] and gives a big cost advantage to labour intensive production of tradable goods in low income countries (like [[Ethiopia]]), as against high income countries (like [[Switzerland]]).
 
The corporate cost advantage is nothing more sophisticated than access to cheaper workers, but because the pay of those workers goes farther in low-income countries than high, the relative pay differentials (inter-country) can be sustained for longer than would be the case otherwise. (This is another way of saying that the wage rate is based on average local productivity and that this is below the per capita productivity that factories selling tradable goods to international markets can achieve.) An equivalent [[cost]] benefit comes from non-traded goods that can be sourced locally (nearer the PPP-exchange rate than the nominal exchange rate in which receipts are paid). These act as a cheaper [[factor of production]] than is available to factories in richer countries.
 
The Bhagwati–Kravis–Lipsey view provides a somewhat different explanation from the Balassa–Samuelson theory. This view states that price levels for nontradables are lower in poorer countries because of differences in endowment of labor and capital, not because of lower levels of productivity. Poor countries have more labor relative to capital, so marginal productivity of labor is greater in rich countries than in poor countries. Nontradables tend to be labor-intensive; therefore, because labor is less expensive in poor countries and is used mostly for nontradables, nontradables are cheaper in poor countries. Wages are high in rich countries, so nontradables are relatively more expensive.<ref name="Krugman"/>
 
PPP calculations tend to overemphasise the primary sectoral contribution, and underemphasise the industrial and service sectoral contributions to the economy of a nation.
 
===Trade barriers and nontradables===
The law of one price, the underlying mechanism behind PPP, is weakened by transport costs and governmental trade restrictions, which make it expensive to move goods between markets located in different countries. Transport costs sever the link between exchange rates and the prices of goods implied by the law of one price. As transport costs increase, the larger the range of exchange rate fluctuations. The same is true for official trade restrictions because the customs fees affect importers' profits in the same way as shipping fees. According to Krugman and Obstfeld, "Either type of trade impediment weakens the basis of PPP by allowing the purchasing power of a given currency to differ more widely from country to country."<ref name=Krugman>{{cite book|last=Krugman and Obstfeld|title=International Economics|year=2009|publisher=Pearson Education, Inc.|pages=394–395}}</ref>  They cite the example that a dollar in London should purchase the same goods as a dollar in Chicago, which is certainly not the case.
 
Nontradables are primarily services and the output of the construction industry. Nontradables also lead to deviations in PPP because the prices of nontradables are not linked internationally. The prices are determined by domestic supply and demand, and shifts in those curves lead to changes in the market basket of some goods relative to the foreign price of the same basket. If the prices of nontradables rise, the purchasing power of any given currency will fall in that country.<ref name="Krugman"/>
 
===Departures from free competition===
Linkages between national price levels are also weakened when trade barriers and imperfectly competitive market structures occur together. Pricing to market occurs when a firm sells the same product for different prices in different markets. This is a reflection of inter-country differences in conditions on both the demand side (''e.g.'', virtually no demand for pork or alcohol in Islamic states) and the supply side (''e.g.'', whether the existing market for a prospective entrant's product features few suppliers or instead is already near-saturated). According to Krugman and Obstfeld, this occurrence of product differentiation and segmented markets results in violations of the law of one price and absolute PPP. Over time, shifts in market structure and demand will occur, which may invalidate relative PPP.<ref name="Krugman"/>
 
===Differences in price level measurement===
Measurement of price levels differ from country to country. Inflation data from different countries are based on different commodity baskets; therefore, exchange rate changes do not offset official measures of inflation differences. Because it makes predictions about price changes rather than price levels, relative PPP is still a useful concept. However, change in the relative prices of basket components can cause relative PPP to fail tests that are based on official price indexes.<ref name="Krugman"/>
 
==Global poverty line==
The global poverty line is a worldwide count of people who live below an international [[poverty line]], referred to as the dollar-a-day line. This line represents an average of the national poverty lines of the [[least developed country|world's poorest countries]], expressed in international dollars.  These national poverty lines are converted to international currency and the global line is converted back to local currency using the PPP exchange rates from the ICP.
 
==See also==
{{Portal|Business and economics}}
 
* [[Big Mac Index]]
* [[International dollar]]
* [[List of countries by GDP (PPP)]]
* [[List of countries by GDP (PPP) per capita]]
* [[Measures of national income and output]]
* [[Relative purchasing power parity]]
 
'''Concepts:'''
* [[Geary–Khamis dollar]]
* [[Karl Gustav Cassel]]
* [[Penn effect]]
 
==References ==
{{Reflist|2}}
 
==External links==
* [http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/ Penn World Table]
* [http://fx.sauder.ubc.ca/PPP.html Explanations from the U. of British Columbia] (also provides daily updated PPP charts)
* [http://www.oecd.org/std/ppp OECD Purchasing Power Parity estimates] updated annually by the Organization for Economic Co-Operation and Development (OECD)
*[http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/statistics_explained/index.php/Purchasing_power_parities_as_example_of_international_statistical_cooperation Purchasing power parities as example of international statistical cooperation] from Eurostat - Statistics Explained
* [http://www.worldbank.org/data/icp World Bank International Comparison Project] provides PPP estimates for a large number of countries
* [http://www.ubs.com/1/ShowMedia/ubs_ch/wealth_mgmt_ch?contentId=103982&name=eng.pdf UBS's "Prices and Earnings" Report 2006] Good report on purchasing power containing a Big Mac index as well as for staples such as bread and rice for 71 world cities.
* [http://pwt.econ.upenn.edu/papers/deaton%20heston%20complete%20nov10.pdf "Understanding PPPs and PPP based national accounts"] provides an overview of methodological issues in calculating PPP and in designing the ICP under which the main PPP tables (Maddison, Penn World Tables, and World Bank WDI) are based
 
{{economics}}
 
{{DEFAULTSORT:Purchasing Power Parity}}
[[Category:Economic indicators]]
[[Category:Gross domestic product]]
[[Category:Index numbers]]
[[Category:International economics]]

Revision as of 06:44, 28 January 2014

GDP per capita by countries in 2013, calculated using PPP exchange rates[1]

In economics, purchasing power parity (PPP) is a component of some economic theories and is a technique used to determine the relative value of different currencies.

Theories that invoke purchasing power parity assume that in some circumstances (for example, as a long-run tendency) it would cost exactly the same number of, say, US dollars to buy euros and then to use the proceeds to buy a market basket of goods as it would cost to use those dollars directly in purchasing the market basket of goods.

The concept of purchasing power parity allows one to estimate what the exchange rate between two currencies would have to be in order for the exchange to be on par with the purchasing power of the two countries' currencies. Using that PPP rate for hypothetical currency conversions, a given amount of one currency thus has the same purchasing power whether used directly to purchase a market basket of goods or used to convert at the PPP rate to the other currency and then purchase the market basket using that currency. Observed deviations of the exchange rate from purchasing power parity are measured by deviations of the real exchange rate from its PPP value of 1.

PPP exchange rates help to avoid misleading international comparisons that can arise with the use of market exchange rates. For example, suppose that two countries produce the same physical amounts of goods as each other in each of two different years. Since market exchange rates fluctuate substantially, when the GDP of one country measured in its own currency is converted to the other country's currency using market exchange rates, one country might be inferred to have higher real GDP than the other country in one year but lower in the other; both of these inferences would fail to reflect the reality of their relative levels of production. But if one country's GDP is converted into the other country's currency using PPP exchange rates instead of observed market exchange rates, the false inference will not occur.

Concept

The idea originated with the School of Salamanca in the 16th century and was developed in its modern form by Gustav Cassel in 1918.[2][3] The concept is based on the law of one price, where in the absence of transaction costs and official trade barriers, identical goods will have the same price in different markets when the prices are expressed in the same currency.[4]

Another interpretation is that the difference in the rate of change in prices at home and abroad—the difference in the inflation rates—is equal to the percentage depreciation or appreciation of the exchange rate.

Deviations from parity imply differences in purchasing power of a "basket of goods" across countries, which means that for the purposes of many international comparisons, countries' GDPs or other national income statistics need to be "PPP-adjusted" and converted into common units. The best-known purchasing power adjustment is the Geary–Khamis dollar (the "international dollar"). The real exchange rate is then equal to the nominal exchange rate, adjusted for differences in price levels. If purchasing power parity held exactly, then the real exchange rate would always equal one. However, in practice the real exchange rates exhibit both short run and long run deviations from this value, for example due to reasons illuminated in the Balassa–Samuelson theorem.

There can be marked differences between purchasing power adjusted incomes and those converted via market exchange rates.[5] For example, the World Bank's World Development Indicators 2005 estimated that in 2003, one Geary-Khamis dollar was equivalent to about 1.8 Chinese yuan by purchasing power parity[6]—considerably different from the nominal exchange rate. This discrepancy has large implications; for instance, when converted via the nominal exchange rates GDP per capita in India is about US$1,704[7] while on a PPP basis it is about US$3,608.[8] At the other extreme, Denmark's nominal GDP per capita is around US$62,100, but its PPP figure is US$37,304.

Functions

The purchasing power parity exchange rate serves two main functions. PPP exchange rates can be useful for making comparisons between countries because they stay fairly constant from day to day or week to week and only change modestly, if at all, from year to year. Second, over a period of years, exchange rates do tend to move in the general direction of the PPP exchange rate and there is some value to knowing in which direction the exchange rate is more likely to shift over the long run.

Among other uses, PPP rates facilitate international comparisons of income, as market exchange rates are often volatile, being affected by political and financial factors that do not lead to immediate changes in income and tend to systematically understate the standard of living in poor countries, due to the Balassa–Samuelson effect.

Measurement

The PPP exchange-rate calculation is controversial because of the difficulties of finding comparable baskets of goods to compare purchasing power across countries.Potter or Ceramic Artist Truman Bedell from Rexton, has interests which include ceramics, best property developers in singapore developers in singapore and scrabble. Was especially enthused after visiting Alejandro de Humboldt National Park.

Estimation of purchasing power parity is complicated by the fact that countries do not simply differ in a uniform price level; rather, the difference in food prices may be greater than the difference in housing prices, while also less than the difference in entertainment prices. People in different countries typically consume different baskets of goods. It is necessary to compare the cost of baskets of goods and services using a price index. This is a difficult task because purchasing patterns and even the goods available to purchase differ across countries.

Thus, it is necessary to make adjustments for differences in the quality of goods and services. Furthermore, the basket of goods representative of one economy will vary from that of another: Americans eat more bread; Chinese more rice. Hence a PPP calculated using the US consumption as a base will differ from that calculated using China as a base. Additional statistical difficulties arise with multilateral comparisons when (as is usually the case) more than two countries are to be compared.

Various ways of averaging bilateral PPPs can provide a more stable multilateral comparison, but at the cost of distorting bilateral ones. These are all general issues of indexing; as with other price indices there is no way to reduce complexity to a single number that is equally satisfying for all purposes. Nevertheless, PPPs are typically robust in the face of the many problems that arise in using market exchange rates to make comparisons.

For example, in 2005 the price of a gallon of gasoline in Saudi Arabia was USD 0.91, and in Norway the price was USD 6.27.[9] The significant differences in price wouldn't contribute to accuracy in a PPP analysis, despite all of the variables that contribute to the significant differences in price. More comparisons have to be made and used as variables in the overall formulation of the PPP.

When PPP comparisons are to be made over some interval of time, proper account needs to be made of inflationary effects.

Law of one price

Although it may seem as if PPPs and the law of one price are the same, there is a difference: the law of one price applies to individual commodities whereas PPP applies to the general price level. If the law of one price is true for all commodities then PPP is also therefore true; however, when discussing the validity of PPP, some argue that the law of one price does not need to be true exactly for PPP to be valid. If the law of one price is not true for a certain commodity, the price levels will not differ enough from the level predicted by PPP.[4]

The purchasing power parity theory states that the exchange rate between one currency and another currency is in equlibirium when their domestic purchasing powers at that rate of exchange are equivalent.

Big Mac Index

Big Mac hamburgers, like this one from Japan, are similar worldwide.

Mining Engineer (Excluding Oil ) Truman from Alma, loves to spend time knotting, largest property developers in singapore developers in singapore and stamp collecting. Recently had a family visit to Urnes Stave Church. An example of one measure of the law of one price, which underlies purchasing power parity, is the Big Mac Index, popularized by The Economist, which compares the prices of a Big Mac burger in McDonald's restaurants in different countries. The Big Mac Index is presumably useful because although it is based on a single consumer product that may not be typical, it is a relatively standardized product that includes input costs from a wide range of sectors in the local economy, such as agricultural commodities (beef, bread, lettuce, cheese), labor (blue and white collar), advertising, rent and real estate costs, transportation, etc.

In theory, the law of one price would hold that if, to take an example, the Canadian dollar were to be significantly overvalued relative to the U.S. dollar according to the Big Mac Index, that gap should be unsustainable because Canadians would import their Big Macs from or travel to the U.S. to consume them, thus putting upward demand pressure on the U.S. dollar by virtue of Canadians buying the U.S. dollars needed to purchase the U.S.-made Big Macs and simultaneously placing downward supply pressure on the Canadian dollar by virtue of Canadians selling their currency in order to buy those same U.S. dollars.

The alternative to this exchange rate adjustment would be an adjustment in prices, with Canadian McDonald's stores compelled to lower prices to remain competitive. Either way, the valuation difference should be reduced assuming perfect competition and a perfectly tradable good. In practice, of course, the Big Mac is not a perfectly tradable good and there may also be capital flows that sustain relative demand for the Canadian dollar. The difference in price may have its origins in a variety of factors besides direct input costs such as government regulations and product differentiation.[4]

In some emerging economies, western fast food represents an expensive niche product price well above the price of traditional staples—i.e. the Big Mac is not a mainstream 'cheap' meal as it is in the West, but a luxury import. This relates back to the idea of product differentiation: the fact that few substitutes for the Big Mac are available confers market power on McDonald's. Additionally, with countries like Argentina that have abundant beef resources, consumer prices in general may not be as cheap as implied by the price of a Big Mac.

The following table, based on data from The Economist's January 2013 calculations, shows the under (−) and over (+) valuation of the local currency against the U.S. dollar in %, according to the Big Mac index. To take an example calculation, the local price of a Big Mac in Hong Kong when converted to U.S. dollars at the market exchange rate was $2.19, or 50% of the local price for a Big Mac in the U.S. of $4.37. Hence the Hong Kong dollar was deemed to be 50% undervalued relative to the U.S. dollar on a PPP basis.

Country Price level (% relative to the US)[10]
Argentina −13
Australia +12
Austria +5
Belgium +18
Brazil +29
Canada +24
Chile 0
China −41
Colombia +11
Costa Rica +1
Czech Republic −15
Estonia −16
Denmark +19
Egypt −45
Euro area +12
Finland +17
France +12
Germany +13
Greece +3
Hong Kong −50
Hungary −13
India −63
Indonesia −35
Ireland +8
Israel −8
Italy +20
Japan −20
Latvia −25
Lithuania −30
Malaysia −41
Mexico −34
Netherlands +7
New Zealand −1
Norway +80
Pakistan −32
Peru −11
Philippines −33
Poland −33
Portugal −8
Russia −45
Saudi Arabia −33
Singapore −17
South Africa −54
South Korea −22
Spain +9
Sri Lanka −37
Sweden +75
Switzerland +63
Taiwan −42
Thailand −33
Turkey +10
UAE −25
Ukraine −47
United Kingdom −3
United States 0
Uruguay +25
Venezuela +108

iPad Index

Like the Big Mac Index, the iPad index (elaborated by ComSec) compares an item's price in various locations. Unlike the Big Mac, however, each iPad is produced in the same place and all iPads (within the same model) have identical performance characteristics. Price differences are therefore a function of transportation costs, taxes, and to a lesser extent, the prices that may be realized in individual markets. It is worth noting that an iPad will cost about twice as much in Argentina as in the United States.

Country Price (US Dollars)[11][12][13][14]
Argentina $1,094.11
Australia $506.66
Austria $674.96
Belgium $618.34
Brazil $791.40
Brunei $525.52
Canada (Montréal) $557.18
Canada (no tax) $484.61
Chile $602.13
China $602.52
Czech Republic $676.69
Denmark $725.32
Finland $695.25
France $688.49
Germany $618.34
Greece $715.54
Hong Kong $501.52
Hungary $679.64
India $512.61
Ireland $630.73
Italy $674.96
Japan $501.56
Luxembourg $641.50
Malaysia $473.77
Mexico $591.62
Netherlands $683.08
New Zealand $610.45
Norway $655.92
Philippines $556.42
Poland $704.51
Portugal $688.49
Russia $596.08
Singapore $525.98
Slovakia $674.96
Slovenia $674.96
South Africa $559.38
South Korea $576.20
Spain $674.96
Sweden $706.87
Switzerland $617.58
Taiwan $538.34
Thailand $530.72
Turkey $656.96
UAE $544.32
United Kingdom $638.81
US (California) $546.91
US (no tax) $499.00
Viêtnam $554.08

OECD comparative price levels

Each month, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development measures the difference in price levels between its member countries by calculating the ratios of PPPs for private final consumption expenditure to exchange rates. The OECD table below indicates the number of US dollars needed, as of January 2014, in each of the countries listed to buy the same representative basket of consumer goods and services that would cost 100 USD in the United States.

According to the table, an American living or travelling in Switzerland on an income denominated in US dollars would find that country (in January 2014) to be the most expensive of the group, having to spend 69% more US dollars to maintain a standard of living comparable to the USA in terms of consumption.

Country Price level (USA = 100)[15]
Australia 145
Austria 116
Belgium 119
Canada 121
Chile 73
Czech Republic 75
Denmark 154
Estonia 84
Finland 133
France 118
Germany 111
Greece 98
Hungary 65
Iceland 122
Ireland 126
Israel 121
Italy 112
Japan 113
Korea 86
Luxembourg 135
Mexico 72
Netherlands 119
New Zealand 130
Norway 161
Poland 63
Portugal 94
Slovakia 77
Slovenia 93
Spain 106
Sweden 135
Switzerland 169
Turkey 67
United Kingdom 125
United States 100

Measurement issues

In addition to methodological issues presented by the selection of a basket of goods, PPP estimates can also vary based on the statistical capacity of participating countries. The International Comparison Program, which PPP estimates are based on, require the disaggregation of national accounts into production, expenditure or (in some cases) income, and not all participating countries routinely disaggregate their data into such categories.

Some aspects of PPP comparison are theoretically impossible or unclear. For example, there is no basis for comparison between the Ethiopian laborer who lives on teff with the Thai laborer who lives on rice, because teff is not commercially available in Thailand and rice is not in Ethiopia, so the price of rice in Ethiopia or teff in Thailand cannot be determined. As a general rule, the more similar the price structure between countries, the more valid the PPP comparison.

PPP levels will also vary based on the formula used to calculate price matrices. Different possible formulas include GEKS-Fisher, Geary-Khamis, IDB, and the superlative method. Each has advantages and disadvantages.

Linking regions presents another methodological difficulty. In the 2005 ICP round, regions were compared by using a list of some 1,000 identical items for which a price could be found for 18 countries, selected so that at least two countries would be in each region. While this was superior to earlier "bridging" methods, which do not fully take into account differing quality between goods, it may serve to overstate the PPP basis of poorer countries, because the price indexing on which PPP is based will assign to poorer countries the greater weight of goods consumed in greater shares in richer countries.

Need for adjustments to GDP

People are nonetheless rushing to buy properties in Singapore. A new residential condominium mission in Bedok had a long queue three days before its official launch and bought more than 350 units on the very first day. Nonetheless, there is a ‘development' that had emerged in 2011 that the majority have possibly overlooked.

In August, more than a hundred individuals across 16 states reportedly had been sickened with salmonella after consuming mangos In September, the Meals and Drug Administration detained mango imports from a Mexican packing house after the fruits had been linked to the sickenings Save Cash On Your Online Purchasing Make saving money when purchasing on-line a breeze with Bodge's favourite app, Invisible Hands. This helpful program does the price-checking analysis for you, and will warn you when a unique site has a better value - or let you realize that you have found the most effective deal. Watch Posted by Edison Foo September 29, 2013 HEARTH SALE!!! From only $9xx,000! We hope this listing will help launch your search for new properties in Singapore. It's unlawful to purchase ice cream after 6 pm, in Newark.

for a borrower with one or more excellent residential property loans3; and No SSD will be payable by the seller if the property is bought more than three years after it was bought. Non-extension of the Jan 2009 Funds assistance measures for the property market when the measures expire. Permitting up to 2 years of property tax deferral for land accepted for improvement. Lively secondary marketplace for easy exit of property investments. Curiosity on mortgage fee is tax deductible when the property is rented out. We've progressive property tax rates for residential properties- the higher the value of the residential property, the upper the tax charge. Why do I've to pay property tax on my house when I'm an onwer-occupier and not deriving rental earnings? Palacio Cluster Landed

After obtaining a Sale License (topic to authorities circumstances meant to guard individuals shopping for property in Singapore), he might www.rmmonline.com proceed to sell units in his growth. Funding in the property market of Singapore is likely one of the few investment choices the place utilizing the bank's cash could not be any easier. The power of expats, to make a down payment, leverage the capital and consequently improve total return on investment, is excessive in Singapore. PRs who own a HDB flat must sell their flat inside six months of buying a non-public residential property in Singapore. EVERLASTING residents (PRs) now face unprecedented limits on their skill to purchase property in Singapore. New Condo in 2013 March Foreigners are eligible for Singapore greenback mortgage loan. housing grant

Skilled property brokers in Singapore will assist the client and defend their interests throughout the acquisition, and will help safe the provide at the best possible price. The agents may even be sure that all paperwork are in order and that the vendor is the rightful proprietor of the property. Most of the property brokers share their databases with each other. Tuesday's measures come after the Monetary Authority of Singapore in June tightened rules on property loans, and closed loopholes that allowed some householders to circumvent loan restrictions and avoid paying levies when buying extra property. Contact us for a FREE housing loan analysis and to study concerning the newest mortgage to worth on Singapore housing loans. J Gateway Condominium (Bought Out) Oct, 2013

6. Completion of automotive park, roads and drains serving the housing project 5% 7. Notice of Vacant Possession (Upon obtaining Temporary Occupation Permit) The estimates given by SingaporeHousingLoan.SG's calculator are not quotations and are usually not binding in any way on SingaporeHousingLoan.sg or the consumer. The method of calculation does not exactly mirror that of which is being used by the individual monetary establishment and the data provided should be used as a information only. SingaporeHousingLoan.SG's calculator does not pre-qualify you for any housing loan from any monetary institution. Undercover Report Finds Unlawful Rat Meat Sold In London Market Unpasteurized Tempeh Linked To Salmonella Outbreak That Sickens 60 Hottest EC Launch in Sengkang!

BuyRentSingaporeProperty.com is dedicated in providing the newest residential launches, Developer's sales, new launches, resale, HIGH tasks and rental of properties in Singapore. Then there are new launch property condos in the mid-tier range. These are sometimes in the vicinity of the city fringe, in areas corresponding to Newton and Novena Tanjong Rhu. These new launch projects are popular due to their proximity to town heart, the place the enterprise and entertainment centers and all the amenities they provide, but they're usually cheaper than the City core region tasks. Why submit cheques to register for new property launches in Singapore? Riversails Apartment @ Higher Serangoon LakeVille @ Jurong Lakeside Condo by MCL Ferra Condo @ Leonie Hill

The exchange rate reflects transaction values for traded goods between countries in contrast to non-traded goods, that is, goods produced for home-country use. Also, currencies are traded for purposes other than trade in goods and services, e.g., to buy capital assets whose prices vary more than those of physical goods. Also, different interest rates, speculation, hedging or interventions by central banks can influence the foreign-exchange market.

The PPP method is used as an alternative to correct for possible statistical bias. The Penn World Table is a widely cited source of PPP adjustments, and the so-called Penn effect reflects such a systematic bias in using exchange rates to outputs among countries.

For example, if the value of the Mexican peso falls by half compared to the US dollar, the Mexican Gross Domestic Product measured in dollars will also halve. However, this exchange rate results from international trade and financial markets. It does not necessarily mean that Mexicans are poorer by a half; if incomes and prices measured in pesos stay the same, they will be no worse off assuming that imported goods are not essential to the quality of life of individuals. Measuring income in different countries using PPP exchange rates helps to avoid this problem.

PPP exchange rates are especially useful when official exchange rates are artificially manipulated by governments. Countries with strong government control of the economy sometimes enforce official exchange rates that make their own currency artificially strong. By contrast, the currency's black market exchange rate is artificially weak. In such cases, a PPP exchange rate is likely the most realistic basis for economic comparison.

Updating PPP rates for GDP

Since global PPP estimates —such as those provided by the ICP— are not calculated annually, but for a single year, PPP exchange rates for years other than the benchmark year need to be updated. This is done using the country's GDP deflator. To calculate a country's PPP exchange rate in Geary–Khamis dollars for a particular year, the calculation proceeds in the following manner:

Where PPPrateX,i is the PPP exchange rate of country X for year i, PPPrateX,b is the PPP exchange rate of country X for the benchmark year, PPPrateU,b is the PPP exchange rate of the United States (US) for the benchmark year (equal to 1), GDPdefX,i is the GDP deflator of country X for year i, GDPdefX,b is the GDP deflator of country X for the benchmark year, GDPdefU,i is the GDP deflator of the US for year i, and GDPdefU,b is the GDP deflator of the US for the benchmark year.

Difficulties

There are a number of reasons that different measures do not perfectly reflect standards of living.

Range and quality of goods

The goods that the currency has the "power" to purchase are a basket of goods of different types:

  1. Local, non-tradable goods and services (like electric power) that are produced and sold domestically.
  2. Tradable goods such as non-perishable commodities that can be sold on the international market (like diamonds).

The more that a product falls into category 1, the more that its price will be from the currency exchange rate, moving towards the PPP exchange rate. Conversely, category 2 products tend to trade close to the currency exchange rate. (See also Penn effect).

More processed and expensive products are likely to be tradable, falling into the second category, and drifting from the PPP exchange rate to the currency exchange rate. Even if the PPP "value" of the Ethiopian currency is three times stronger than the currency exchange rate, it won't buy three times as much of internationally traded goods like steel, cars and microchips, but non-traded goods like housing, services ("haircuts"), and domestically produced crops. The relative price differential between tradables and non-tradables from high-income to low-income countries is a consequence of the Balassa–Samuelson effect and gives a big cost advantage to labour intensive production of tradable goods in low income countries (like Ethiopia), as against high income countries (like Switzerland).

The corporate cost advantage is nothing more sophisticated than access to cheaper workers, but because the pay of those workers goes farther in low-income countries than high, the relative pay differentials (inter-country) can be sustained for longer than would be the case otherwise. (This is another way of saying that the wage rate is based on average local productivity and that this is below the per capita productivity that factories selling tradable goods to international markets can achieve.) An equivalent cost benefit comes from non-traded goods that can be sourced locally (nearer the PPP-exchange rate than the nominal exchange rate in which receipts are paid). These act as a cheaper factor of production than is available to factories in richer countries.

The Bhagwati–Kravis–Lipsey view provides a somewhat different explanation from the Balassa–Samuelson theory. This view states that price levels for nontradables are lower in poorer countries because of differences in endowment of labor and capital, not because of lower levels of productivity. Poor countries have more labor relative to capital, so marginal productivity of labor is greater in rich countries than in poor countries. Nontradables tend to be labor-intensive; therefore, because labor is less expensive in poor countries and is used mostly for nontradables, nontradables are cheaper in poor countries. Wages are high in rich countries, so nontradables are relatively more expensive.[4]

PPP calculations tend to overemphasise the primary sectoral contribution, and underemphasise the industrial and service sectoral contributions to the economy of a nation.

Trade barriers and nontradables

The law of one price, the underlying mechanism behind PPP, is weakened by transport costs and governmental trade restrictions, which make it expensive to move goods between markets located in different countries. Transport costs sever the link between exchange rates and the prices of goods implied by the law of one price. As transport costs increase, the larger the range of exchange rate fluctuations. The same is true for official trade restrictions because the customs fees affect importers' profits in the same way as shipping fees. According to Krugman and Obstfeld, "Either type of trade impediment weakens the basis of PPP by allowing the purchasing power of a given currency to differ more widely from country to country."[4] They cite the example that a dollar in London should purchase the same goods as a dollar in Chicago, which is certainly not the case.

Nontradables are primarily services and the output of the construction industry. Nontradables also lead to deviations in PPP because the prices of nontradables are not linked internationally. The prices are determined by domestic supply and demand, and shifts in those curves lead to changes in the market basket of some goods relative to the foreign price of the same basket. If the prices of nontradables rise, the purchasing power of any given currency will fall in that country.[4]

Departures from free competition

Linkages between national price levels are also weakened when trade barriers and imperfectly competitive market structures occur together. Pricing to market occurs when a firm sells the same product for different prices in different markets. This is a reflection of inter-country differences in conditions on both the demand side (e.g., virtually no demand for pork or alcohol in Islamic states) and the supply side (e.g., whether the existing market for a prospective entrant's product features few suppliers or instead is already near-saturated). According to Krugman and Obstfeld, this occurrence of product differentiation and segmented markets results in violations of the law of one price and absolute PPP. Over time, shifts in market structure and demand will occur, which may invalidate relative PPP.[4]

Differences in price level measurement

Measurement of price levels differ from country to country. Inflation data from different countries are based on different commodity baskets; therefore, exchange rate changes do not offset official measures of inflation differences. Because it makes predictions about price changes rather than price levels, relative PPP is still a useful concept. However, change in the relative prices of basket components can cause relative PPP to fail tests that are based on official price indexes.[4]

Global poverty line

The global poverty line is a worldwide count of people who live below an international poverty line, referred to as the dollar-a-day line. This line represents an average of the national poverty lines of the world's poorest countries, expressed in international dollars. These national poverty lines are converted to international currency and the global line is converted back to local currency using the PPP exchange rates from the ICP.

See also

Sportspersons Hyslop from Nicolet, usually spends time with pastimes for example martial arts, property developers condominium in singapore singapore and hot rods. Maintains a trip site and has lots to write about after touring Gulf of Porto: Calanche of Piana.

Concepts:

References

43 year old Petroleum Engineer Harry from Deep River, usually spends time with hobbies and interests like renting movies, property developers in singapore new condominium and vehicle racing. Constantly enjoys going to destinations like Camino Real de Tierra Adentro.

External links

Template:Economics

  1. Based on figures from CIA world factbook
  2. One of the biggest reasons investing in a Singapore new launch is an effective things is as a result of it is doable to be lent massive quantities of money at very low interest rates that you should utilize to purchase it. Then, if property values continue to go up, then you'll get a really high return on funding (ROI). Simply make sure you purchase one of the higher properties, reminiscent of the ones at Fernvale the Riverbank or any Singapore landed property Get Earnings by means of Renting

    In its statement, the singapore property listing - website link, government claimed that the majority citizens buying their first residence won't be hurt by the new measures. Some concessions can even be prolonged to chose teams of consumers, similar to married couples with a minimum of one Singaporean partner who are purchasing their second property so long as they intend to promote their first residential property. Lower the LTV limit on housing loans granted by monetary establishments regulated by MAS from 70% to 60% for property purchasers who are individuals with a number of outstanding housing loans on the time of the brand new housing purchase. Singapore Property Measures - 30 August 2010 The most popular seek for the number of bedrooms in Singapore is 4, followed by 2 and three. Lush Acres EC @ Sengkang

    Discover out more about real estate funding in the area, together with info on international funding incentives and property possession. Many Singaporeans have been investing in property across the causeway in recent years, attracted by comparatively low prices. However, those who need to exit their investments quickly are likely to face significant challenges when trying to sell their property – and could finally be stuck with a property they can't sell. Career improvement programmes, in-house valuation, auctions and administrative help, venture advertising and marketing, skilled talks and traisning are continuously planned for the sales associates to help them obtain better outcomes for his or her shoppers while at Knight Frank Singapore. No change Present Rules

    Extending the tax exemption would help. The exemption, which may be as a lot as $2 million per family, covers individuals who negotiate a principal reduction on their existing mortgage, sell their house short (i.e., for lower than the excellent loans), or take part in a foreclosure course of. An extension of theexemption would seem like a common-sense means to assist stabilize the housing market, but the political turmoil around the fiscal-cliff negotiations means widespread sense could not win out. Home Minority Chief Nancy Pelosi (D-Calif.) believes that the mortgage relief provision will be on the table during the grand-cut price talks, in response to communications director Nadeam Elshami. Buying or promoting of blue mild bulbs is unlawful.

    A vendor's stamp duty has been launched on industrial property for the primary time, at rates ranging from 5 per cent to 15 per cent. The Authorities might be trying to reassure the market that they aren't in opposition to foreigners and PRs investing in Singapore's property market. They imposed these measures because of extenuating components available in the market." The sale of new dual-key EC models will even be restricted to multi-generational households only. The models have two separate entrances, permitting grandparents, for example, to dwell separately. The vendor's stamp obligation takes effect right this moment and applies to industrial property and plots which might be offered inside three years of the date of buy. JLL named Best Performing Property Brand for second year running

    The data offered is for normal info purposes only and isn't supposed to be personalised investment or monetary advice. Motley Fool Singapore contributor Stanley Lim would not personal shares in any corporations talked about. Singapore private home costs increased by 1.eight% within the fourth quarter of 2012, up from 0.6% within the earlier quarter. Resale prices of government-built HDB residences which are usually bought by Singaporeans, elevated by 2.5%, quarter on quarter, the quickest acquire in five quarters. And industrial property, prices are actually double the levels of three years ago. No withholding tax in the event you sell your property. All your local information regarding vital HDB policies, condominium launches, land growth, commercial property and more

    There are various methods to go about discovering the precise property. Some local newspapers (together with the Straits Instances ) have categorised property sections and many local property brokers have websites. Now there are some specifics to consider when buying a 'new launch' rental. Intended use of the unit Every sale begins with 10 p.c low cost for finish of season sale; changes to 20 % discount storewide; follows by additional reduction of fiftyand ends with last discount of 70 % or extra. Typically there is even a warehouse sale or transferring out sale with huge mark-down of costs for stock clearance. Deborah Regulation from Expat Realtor shares her property market update, plus prime rental residences and houses at the moment available to lease Esparina EC @ Sengkang


  3. My name is Dorris Bosanquet but everybody calls me Dorris. I'm from Iceland. I'm studying at the university (3rd year) and I play the Bass Guitar for 5 years. Usually I choose music from my famous films ;).
    I have two sister. I love Knitting, watching movies and Water sports.

    Also visit my blog post - http://Hostgator1Centcoupon.info/ (http://dawonls.dothome.co.kr/db/?document_srl=373691)
  4. 4.0 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 4.7 20 year-old Real Estate Agent Rusty from Saint-Paul, has hobbies and interests which includes monopoly, property developers in singapore and poker. Will soon undertake a contiki trip that may include going to the Lower Valley of the Omo.

    My blog: http://www.primaboinca.com/view_profile.php?userid=5889534 Cite error: Invalid <ref> tag; name "Krugman" defined multiple times with different content
  5. FT.com / World - China, India economies ‘40% smaller’:By Scheherazade Daneshkhu in London Published: December 18 2007 18:04
  6. 2005 World Development Indicators: Table 5.7 | Relative prices and exchange rates
  7. List of countries by past and future GDP (nominal)
  8. List of countries by future GDP (PPP) per capita estimates
  9. "Global Gas Prices," (March 2005) CNN Money. Accessed June 2011.
  10. [1] The Economist January 2013
  11. [2] The Age 23 September 2013
  12. [3] 23rd Sep 2013, CommSec Economic Insight: CommSec iPad Index Sep 23,2013
  13. [4] Commonwealth Securities 23 September 2013
  14. [5] How much an iPad costs 21 December 2013
  15. [6] OECD July 4, 2013