Lowest common denominator: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
Role in arithmetic and algebra: The line about variables was missing a factor of d. a/bc = abd/b^2cd
en>DavidLeighEllis
m Reverted edits by 107.212.196.241 (talk) to last version by 213.94.254.243
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Technical|date=August 2011}}
Common history of the writer was Adrianne Quesada. Her husband doesn't like one the way she has been doing but what she especially likes doing is to bake but she's thinking on [http://Www.britannica.com/search?query=starting starting] something new. After being out of his job for years he became an order clerk. Vermont are where her house was. Her husband and her always maintain a website. You might need to check it out: http://circuspartypanama.com<br><br>Also visit my web blog :: clash of [http://Clanshack.org/ clans hack] cydia ([http://circuspartypanama.com sneak a peek at this site])
{{Development economics sidebar}}
'''Endogenous growth theory''' holds that [[economic growth]] is primarily the result of [[Endogeneity (economics)|endogenous]] and not external forces.<ref>{{cite journal |journal = [[The Journal of Economic Perspectives]] |volume= 8 |issue= 1 |year= 1994 |first= P. M. |last= Romer |title= The Origins of Endogenous Growth |authorlink= Paul Romer |pages =3–22 |jstor=2138148 }}</ref> Endogenous growth theory holds that investment in [[human capital]], [[innovation]], and knowledge are significant contributors to economic growth. The theory also focuses on [[positive externalities]] and [[spillover effects]] of a knowledge-based economy which will lead to economic development. There are classical, neo-classical and Keynesian theories of growth (see especially the book edited by Neri Salvadori and Carlo Panico, Classical, Neo-Classical and Keynesian Views on Growth and Distribution). The endogenous growth theory primarily holds that the long run growth rate of an economy depends on policy measures. For example, [[subsidies]] for [[research and development]] or [[education]] increase the growth rate in some endogenous growth models by increasing the incentive for innovation.
 
== Models in Endogenous Growth ==
 
In the mid-1980s, a group of growth theorists became increasingly dissatisfied with common accounts of [[exogenous]] factors determining long-run growth. They favored a model that replaced the exogenous growth variable (unexplained technical progress) with a model in which the key determinants of growth were explicit in the model. The initial research was based on the work of [[Kenneth Arrow]] (1962), [[Hirofumi Uzawa]] (1965), and [[Miguel Sidrauski]] (1967).<ref>{{cite web |url= http://www.newschool.edu/nssr/het/essays/growth/moneygrowth.htm |title=Monetary Growth Theory  |work=newschool.edu |year=2011 |accessdate=11 October 2011}}</ref> [[Paul Romer]] (1986), [[Robert Emerson Lucas, Jr.|Robert Lucas]] (1988),<ref>{{cite journal |url= http://www.fordham.edu/economics/mcleod/LucasMechanicsEconomicGrowth.pdf |title= On the mechanics of Economic Development |first= R. E. |last= Lucas |authorlink= Robert Emerson Lucas, Jr. |journal = [[Journal of Monetary Economics]] |year=1988 |volume = 22  }}</ref> and [[Sergio Rebelo]] (1991)<ref>{{cite journal |url=http://www.nber.org/papers/w3325 |title= Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth |first= Sergio |last= Rebelo  |journal = [[Journal of Political Economy]] |year=1991 |volume = 99 |issue= 3 |page= 500 }}</ref><ref>{{cite web |url= http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/public/lecturenotes/Growth/RebeloAK.pdf |title= The Rebelo AK Growth Model  |first= C.|last= Carroll |work=econ2.jhu.edu |year=2011 |accessdate=11 October 2011 |quote= the steady-state growth rate in a Rebelo economy is directly proportional to the saving rate.}}</ref> omitted technological change. Instead, growth in these models was due to indefinite investment in [[human capital]] which had [[spillover effect]] on economy and reduces the diminishing return to [[capital accumulation]].<ref name= "BX">{{cite book |first1= R. J. |last1= Barro |first2= Xavier |authorlink2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=2nd |isbn=0-262-02553-1 }}</ref>
 
The [[AK model]], which is the simplest endogenous model, gives a constant-saving-rate of endogenous growth. It assumes a constant, exogenous, saving rate. It models technological progress with a single parameter (usually A). It uses the assumption that the production function does not exhibit diminishing returns to scale to lead to endogenous growth. Various rationales for this assumption have been given, such as positive spillovers from capital investment to the economy as a whole or  improvements in technology leading to further improvements (i.e. learning-by-doing). However, the endogenous growth theory is further supported with models in which agents optimally determined the consumption and saving, optimizing the resources allocation to research and development leading to technological progress. Romer (1987, 1990) and significant contributions by Aghion and Howitt (1992) and Grossman and Helpman (1991), incorporated [[imperfect market]]s and R&D to the growth model.<ref name= "BX"/>
 
== The AK Model ==
{{main|AK model}}
 
The model works on the property of absence of diminishing returns to capital. The simplest form of production function with diminishing return is:
 
:<math>Y = AK\,</math>
 
where
:<math> A\,</math> , is a positive constant that reflects the level of the technology.
 
:<math> K \,</math> capital (broad sense to include human capital)
 
:<math>y = AK\,</math> , output per capita and the average and marginal product are constant at the level <math>A>0\,</math>
 
If we substitute <math>\frac{f(k)}{k}=A \,</math> in equation of transitional Dynamics of Solow-Swan model ([[Exogenous growth model]]) which shows how an economy’s per capita incomes converges toward its own steady-state value and to the per capita incomes of other nations.
 
Transitional Dynamics equation, where Growth rate on <math> k\,</math> is given by,
 
:<math>\gamma_K=\dot{k}/k = s.f(k)/ k - (n+\delta)\ ,</math>
 
on substituting <math> A\,</math>, we get,
:<math>\gamma_K= sA -(n+\delta)\ ,</math>
 
We return here to the case of zero technological progress, <math> x=0\,</math>, because we want to show that per capita growth can now occur in the long-run even without exogenous technological change. The figure 1.1 explains the perpetual growth, with exogenous technical progress.  The vertical distance between the two line, <math> sA\,</math>and n+δ gives the<math>\gamma_K\,</math>
 
As, <math> sA>\, </math>n+δ, so that<math>\gamma_K > 0\,</math>. Since the two line are parallel, <math>\gamma_K\,</math>is constant; in particular, it is independent of <math>K\,</math>. In other words,<math>K\,</math> always grows at steady states rate,<math>\gamma_K^*= sA -(n+\delta)\ ,</math>.
 
Since
:<math>y = AK\,</math>,<math>\gamma_K\,</math> equals <math>\gamma_K^*\,</math>
 
at every point of time. In addition, since
:<math>c= (1-s) y\,</math>,
 
the growth rate of
:<math>c\,</math> equals <math>\gamma_K^*\,</math>.
 
Hence, the entire per capita variable in the model grows at same rate, given by
:<math>\gamma^*= sA -(n+\delta)\ ,</math>
 
However, we can observe that<math>y = AK\,</math> technology displays a positive long-run per capita growth without any exogenous technological development. The per capita growth depends on behavioural factors of the model as the saving rate and population. It is unlike neoclassical model, which is higher saving, s, promotes higher long-run per capita growth <math>\gamma^*\,</math>.<ref name= "BX"/>
 
== Endogenous versus exogenous growth theory ==
In neo-classical growth models, the long-run rate of growth is [[exogeny|exogenous]]ly determined by either the savings rate (the [[Harrod–Domar model]]) or the rate of technical progress ([[Solow model]]). However, the savings rate and rate of technological progress remain unexplained. Endogenous growth theory tries to overcome this shortcoming by building macroeconomic models out of [[Microfoundations|microeconomic foundations]]. Households are assumed to maximize utility subject to budget constraints while firms maximize profits. Crucial importance is usually given to the production of new technologies and [[human capital]]. The engine for growth can be as simple as a constant return to scale production function (the AK model) or more complicated set ups with [[Knowledge spillover|spillover]] effects (spillovers are positive externalities, benefits that are attributed to costs from other firms), increasing numbers of goods, increasing qualities, etc.
 
Often endogenous growth theory assumes constant marginal product of capital at the aggregate level, or at least that the limit of the marginal product of capital does not tend towards zero. This does not imply that larger firms will be more productive than small ones, because at the firm level the marginal product of capital is still diminishing. Therefore, it is possible to construct endogenous growth models with [[perfect competition]]. However, in many endogenous growth models the assumption of perfect competition is relaxed, and some degree of [[monopoly]] power is thought to exist. Generally monopoly power in these models comes from the holding of patents. These are models with two sectors, producers of final output and an R&D sector. The R&D sector develops ideas that they are granted a monopoly power. R&D firms are assumed to be able to make monopoly profits selling ideas to production firms, but the [[free entry]] condition means that these profits are dissipated on R&D spending.
 
== Implications ==
An Endogenous growth theory implication is that policies which embrace openness, competition, change and innovation will promote growth.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Fadare|first=Samuel O.|title=Recent Banking Sector Reforms and Economic Growth in Nigeria|journal=Middle Eastern Finance and Economics|issue= 8 (2010)|url=http://www.eurojournals.com/MEFE_8_12.pdf}}</ref>  Conversely, policies which have the effect of restricting or slowing change by protecting or favouring particular existing industries or firms are likely over time to slow growth to the disadvantage of the community. [[Peter Howitt (economist)|Peter Howitt]] has written:
<blockquote>
Sustained economic growth is everywhere and always a process of continual transformation. The sort of economic progress that has been enjoyed by the richest nations since the Industrial Revolution would not have been possible if people had not undergone wrenching changes. Economies that cease to transform themselves are destined to fall off the path of economic growth. The countries that most deserve the title of “developing” are not the poorest countries of the world, but the richest. [They] need to engage in the never-ending process of economic development if they are to enjoy continued prosperity. (Conclusion, "Growth and development: a Schumpeterian perspective", 2006 [http://www.cdhowe.org/pdf/commentary_246.pdf]).
</blockquote>
 
== Criticisms ==<!-- This section is linked from [[Economics]] -->
 
One of the main failings of endogenous growth theories is the collective failure to explain [[conditional convergence]] reported in the empirical literature.<ref>See {{cite journal |last=Sachs |first=Jeffrey D. |first2=Andrew M. |last2=Warner |year=1997 |title=Fundamental Sources of Long-Run Growth |journal=[[American Economic Review]] |volume=87 |issue=2 |pages=184–188 |doi= |jstor=2950910 }}</ref> Another frequent critique concerns the cornerstone assumption of diminishing returns to capital. Some{{who|date=February 2013}} contend that new growth theory has proven no more successful than [[Neoclassical growth model|exogenous growth theory]] in explaining the income divergence between the [[developing nation|developing]] and [[developed nation|developed]] worlds (despite usually being more complex).<ref>See for instance, Professor Stephen Parente's 2001 review, ''The Failure of Endogenous Growth'' ([https://netfiles.uiuc.edu/parente/The%20Failure%20of%20Endogenous%20Growth.pdf Online] at the [[University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign]]). (Published in [http://www.metapress.com/(gqdg4dzadovmv5fnfj5jki2x)/home/main.mpx Knowledge Technology & Policy] Volume XIII, Number 4.)</ref> [[Paul Krugman]] criticized endogenous growth theory as nearly impossible to [[Empirical evidence|empirically verify]]; “too much of it involved making assumptions about how unmeasurable things affected other unmeasurable things.”<ref>{{cite news |url=http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/08/18/the-new-growth-fizzle/?_r=0 |title=The New Growth Fizzle |newspaper=New York Times |first=Paul |last=Krugman |date=August 18, 2013 }}</ref>
 
== See also ==
* [[Economic growth]]
* [[Human capital]]
* [[Feldman–Mahalanobis model]]
* [[Solow–Swan model]], “the” exogenous growth model
* [[Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model]], a microfounded growth model with infinite horizon
 
== Notes ==
{{reflist}}
 
== Further reading ==
*{{cite book |first=Daron |last=Acemoglu |chapter=Endogenous Technological Change |title=Introduction to Modern Economic Growth |location= |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-691-13292-1 |pages=411–533 }}
*{{cite book |first1= Robert J. |last1= Barro |authorlink1=Robert J. Barro |first2= Xavier |authorlink2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |chapter=One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=Second |isbn=0-262-02553-1 |pages=205–237 }}
De Liso, N., Filatrella, G., and Weaver N. (2001): “On endogenous growth and increasing returns: modeling learning-by-doing and the division of labor”, ''Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization'', Sept. 2001, Vol. 46, pp. 39-55.
*{{cite book |last=Farmer |first=Roger E. A. |chapter=Endogenous Growth Theory |title=Macroeconomics |location=Cincinnati |publisher=South-Western |year=1999 |edition=Second |isbn=0-324-12058-3 |pages=357–380 }}
*{{cite book |first=David |last=Romer |authorlink=David Romer |chapter=Endogenous Growth |title=Advanced Macroeconomics |edition=Fourth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2011 |pages=101–149 |isbn=978-0-07-351137-5 }}
 
== External links ==
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/EconomicGrowth.html Economic Growth] by [[Paul Romer]].
* [http://www2.stat.unibo.it/mazzocchi/macroeconomia/documenti/Growth.pdf New Growth Theory, Technology and Learning: A Practitioner's Guide], [[Economic Development Administration|U.S. Economic Development Administration]].
* [http://ebookbrowse.com/technological-implications-of-new-growth-theory-for-the-south-pdf-d247642918 Technological Implications of New Growth Theory for the South], [[United Nations Development Programme]].
 
{{Macroeconomics}}
 
[[Category:Economic theories]]
[[Category:Economic growth]]

Revision as of 22:06, 2 March 2014

Common history of the writer was Adrianne Quesada. Her husband doesn't like one the way she has been doing but what she especially likes doing is to bake but she's thinking on starting something new. After being out of his job for years he became an order clerk. Vermont are where her house was. Her husband and her always maintain a website. You might need to check it out: http://circuspartypanama.com

Also visit my web blog :: clash of clans hack cydia (sneak a peek at this site)