RC time constant: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
No edit summary
 
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
Here are some helpful tips and suggestions on what to do if your digital camera gets wet. Professional water damage restoration Services can dramatically reduce the scope of damage and save thousands of dollars in replacement costs. When it's time for restoration for a covered loss, you don't deserve to be short changed. He has several years experience in water damage, fire damage restoration. When bonded to the substrate, laminate offers homeowners a long lasting and strong surface. <br><br>Cracks, splits and holes will first need to be repaired as these hold the potential to undo any waterproofing that you undertake. Sydney is a metropolitan city which is believed to be a highly commercialized region. Condominium insurance covers most water damage similar to home insurance. Article Source: Corkern is a writer and promoter of. Do not compromise with price as the work done will be beautifully executed and the professionals will not leave before finishing the work. <br><br>In 2010, the service provider offers continuing education in disaster recovery, dehumidification, and water damage restoration. Fabric panels do not meet the impact certification test and will not. In other words, until this unprecedented and massive habitat restoration and water diversion project is actually built and operating, no one knows for sure what will happen to individual species or their habitats. When cleaning your carpets, our teams make use of water extraction, this will ensure that your carpets dry quicker.  If you liked this article and you also would like to receive more info regarding [http://www.tuugo.us/Companies/dallas-roofing-consultants/0310006141785 Plano commercial roofing] please visit the page. For this reason, it's also the best place to buy or restore your dream car. <br><br>Get on the phone as soon as such a disaster or issue happens so that experts can come in and talk to you about how to remedy the situation. The sooner the fire cleanup begins, the better the chance that damaged property can be salvaged and permanent damage can be avoided. He would be a Priest forever after the order of Melchizedek. Next include a copy of the signed work authorization and signed certificate of satisfaction. It is east of Flint and known as the county seat of Lapeer. <br><br>There is also the possibility of system failure related to technology, electrical power or communication systems. If you must keep one or more servers up during a long-term power outage, consider a generator. All in all, potential customers can rest assured that their investment in quality carpets, soft furnishings and delicate fabrics will be cleaned to perfection with no adverse effects. Andrew in 1992, the Miami-Dade testing regarded as expecting manufacturers to. You may need sandpapers of 50, 80 or 120 grits to fully remove the loose paint.
[[Image:Contract-curve-on-edgeworth-box.svg|thumb|400px|right|Blue contract curve showing points of tangency of [[indifference curve]]s in an [[Edgeworth box]]]]
 
Any [[Walrasian equilibrium]] lies on the contract curve. As with all points that are Pareto efficient, each point on the contract curve is a point of tangency between an indifference curve of one person and an indifference curve of the other person. Thus, on the contract curve the [[marginal rate of substitution]] is the same for both people.
 
==Example==
Assume the existence of an economy with two agents, Octavio and Abby, who consume two goods X and Y of which there are fixed supplies, as illustrated in the above Edgeworth box diagram. Further, assume an initial distribution (endowment) of the goods between Octavio and Abby and let each have normally structured (convex) preferences represented by [[indifference curves]] that are convex toward the people's respective origins. If the initial allocation is not at a point of tangency between an indifference curve of Octavio and one of Abby, then that initial allocation must be at a point where an indifference curve of Octavio crosses one of Abby. These two indifference curves form a lens shape, with the initial allocation at one of the two corners of the lens. Octavio and Abby will choose to make mutually beneficial trades — that is, they will trade to a point that is on a better (farther from the origin) indifference curve for both. Such a point will be in the interior of the lens, and the rate at which one good will be traded for the other will be between the marginal rate of substitution of Octavio and that of Abby. Since the trades will always provide each person with more of one good and less of the other, trading results in movement upward and to the left, or downward and to the right, in the diagram.
 
The two people will continue to trade so long as each one’s [[marginal rate of substitution]] (the absolute value of the slope of the person's indifference curve at that point) differs from that of the other person at the current allocation (in which case there will be a mutually acceptable trading ratio of one good for the other, between the different marginal rates of substitution). At a point where Octavios’s marginal rate of substitution equals Abby’s marginal rate of substitution, no more mutually beneficial exchange is possible.  This point is called a [[Pareto efficient]] equilibriumIn the Edgeworth box, it is a point at which Octavio’s indifference curve is tangent to Abby’s indifference curve, and it is inside the lens formed by their initial allocations.
 
Thus the contract curve, the set of points Octavio and Abby could end up at, is the section of the Pareto efficient locus that is in the interior of the lens formed by the initial allocations. The analysis cannot say which particular point along the contract curve they will end up at — this depends on the two people's bargaining skills.
 
==Mathematical Explanation==
In the case of two goods and two individuals, the contract curve can be found as follows. Here <math>x_{2}^{1}</math> refers to the final amount of good 2 allocated to person 1, etc., <math>u^1</math> and <math>u^2</math> refer to the final levels of utility experienced by person 1 and person 2 respectively, <math>u_{0}^{2}</math> refers to the level of utility that person 2 would receive from the initial allocation without trading at all, and <math>\omega_{1}^{tot}</math> and <math>\omega_{2}^{tot}</math> refer to the fixed total quantities available of goods 1 and 2 respectively.
 
:<math>\max_{x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1},x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}} u^1(x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1})</math>
 
subject to:
 
:<math>
x_{1}^{1}+x_{1}^{2} \leq \omega_{1}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
x_{2}^{1}+x_{2}^{2} \leq \omega_{2}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
u^2(x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}) \geq u_{0}^{2}
</math>
 
This optimization problem states that the goods are to be allocated between the two people in such a way that no more than the available amount of each good is allocated to the two people combined, and the first person's utility is to be as high as possible while making the second person's utility no lower than at the initial allocation (so the second person would not refuse to trade from the initial allocation to the point found); this formulation of the problem finds a Pareto efficient point on the lens, as far as possible from person 1's origin. This is the point that would be achieved if person 1 had all the bargaining power. (In fact, in order to create at least a slight incentive for person 2 to agree to trade to the identified point, the point would have to be slightly inside the lens.)
 
In order to trace out the entire contract curve, the above optimization problem can be modified as follows. Maximize a weighted average of the utilities of persons 1 and 2, with weights ''b'' and 1 – ''b'', subject to the constraints that the allocations of each good not exceed its supply and subject to the constraints that both people's utilities be at least as great as their utilities at the initial endowments:
 
:<math>\max_{x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1},x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}} b \cdot u^1(x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1})+ (1-b) \cdot u^2(x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2})</math>
 
subject to:
 
:<math>
x_{1}^{1}+x_{1}^{2} \leq \omega_{1}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
x_{2}^{1}+x_{2}^{2} \leq \omega_{2}^{tot}
</math>
 
:<math>
u^1(x_{1}^{1},x_{2}^{1}) \geq u_{0}^{1}
</math>
 
:<math>
u^2(x_{1}^{2},x_{2}^{2}) \geq u_{0}^{2}
</math>
 
where <math>u^1</math> is the utility that person 1 would experience in the absence of trading away from the initial endowment. By varying the weighting parameter ''b'', one can trace out the entire contract curve: If ''b'' = 1 the problem is the same as the previous problem, and it identifies an efficient point at one edge of the lens formed by the indifference curves of the initial endowment; if ''b'' = 0 all the weight is on person 2's utility instead of person 1's, and so the optimization identifies the efficient point on the other edge of the lens. As ''b'' varies smoothly between these two extremes, all the in-between points on the contract curve are traced out.
 
Note that the above optimizations are not ones that the two people would actually engage in, either explicitly or implicitly. Instead, these optimizations are simply a way for the economist to identify points on the contract curve.
 
==See also==
*[[Welfare economics]]
*[[List of economics topics]].
 
==References==
*[[Andreu Mas-Colell|Mas-Colell, Andreu]]; Whinston, Michael D.; & Green, Jerry (1995). ''Microeconomic Theory''. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-510268-1
 
[[Category:Welfare economics]]
[[Category:Economics curves]]

Revision as of 21:15, 11 November 2013

File:Contract-curve-on-edgeworth-box.svg
Blue contract curve showing points of tangency of indifference curves in an Edgeworth box

Any Walrasian equilibrium lies on the contract curve. As with all points that are Pareto efficient, each point on the contract curve is a point of tangency between an indifference curve of one person and an indifference curve of the other person. Thus, on the contract curve the marginal rate of substitution is the same for both people.

Example

Assume the existence of an economy with two agents, Octavio and Abby, who consume two goods X and Y of which there are fixed supplies, as illustrated in the above Edgeworth box diagram. Further, assume an initial distribution (endowment) of the goods between Octavio and Abby and let each have normally structured (convex) preferences represented by indifference curves that are convex toward the people's respective origins. If the initial allocation is not at a point of tangency between an indifference curve of Octavio and one of Abby, then that initial allocation must be at a point where an indifference curve of Octavio crosses one of Abby. These two indifference curves form a lens shape, with the initial allocation at one of the two corners of the lens. Octavio and Abby will choose to make mutually beneficial trades — that is, they will trade to a point that is on a better (farther from the origin) indifference curve for both. Such a point will be in the interior of the lens, and the rate at which one good will be traded for the other will be between the marginal rate of substitution of Octavio and that of Abby. Since the trades will always provide each person with more of one good and less of the other, trading results in movement upward and to the left, or downward and to the right, in the diagram.

The two people will continue to trade so long as each one’s marginal rate of substitution (the absolute value of the slope of the person's indifference curve at that point) differs from that of the other person at the current allocation (in which case there will be a mutually acceptable trading ratio of one good for the other, between the different marginal rates of substitution). At a point where Octavios’s marginal rate of substitution equals Abby’s marginal rate of substitution, no more mutually beneficial exchange is possible. This point is called a Pareto efficient equilibrium. In the Edgeworth box, it is a point at which Octavio’s indifference curve is tangent to Abby’s indifference curve, and it is inside the lens formed by their initial allocations.

Thus the contract curve, the set of points Octavio and Abby could end up at, is the section of the Pareto efficient locus that is in the interior of the lens formed by the initial allocations. The analysis cannot say which particular point along the contract curve they will end up at — this depends on the two people's bargaining skills.

Mathematical Explanation

In the case of two goods and two individuals, the contract curve can be found as follows. Here x21 refers to the final amount of good 2 allocated to person 1, etc., u1 and u2 refer to the final levels of utility experienced by person 1 and person 2 respectively, u02 refers to the level of utility that person 2 would receive from the initial allocation without trading at all, and ω1tot and ω2tot refer to the fixed total quantities available of goods 1 and 2 respectively.

maxx11,x21,x12,x22u1(x11,x21)

subject to:

x11+x12ω1tot
x21+x22ω2tot
u2(x12,x22)u02

This optimization problem states that the goods are to be allocated between the two people in such a way that no more than the available amount of each good is allocated to the two people combined, and the first person's utility is to be as high as possible while making the second person's utility no lower than at the initial allocation (so the second person would not refuse to trade from the initial allocation to the point found); this formulation of the problem finds a Pareto efficient point on the lens, as far as possible from person 1's origin. This is the point that would be achieved if person 1 had all the bargaining power. (In fact, in order to create at least a slight incentive for person 2 to agree to trade to the identified point, the point would have to be slightly inside the lens.)

In order to trace out the entire contract curve, the above optimization problem can be modified as follows. Maximize a weighted average of the utilities of persons 1 and 2, with weights b and 1 – b, subject to the constraints that the allocations of each good not exceed its supply and subject to the constraints that both people's utilities be at least as great as their utilities at the initial endowments:

maxx11,x21,x12,x22bu1(x11,x21)+(1b)u2(x12,x22)

subject to:

x11+x12ω1tot
x21+x22ω2tot
u1(x11,x21)u01
u2(x12,x22)u02

where u1 is the utility that person 1 would experience in the absence of trading away from the initial endowment. By varying the weighting parameter b, one can trace out the entire contract curve: If b = 1 the problem is the same as the previous problem, and it identifies an efficient point at one edge of the lens formed by the indifference curves of the initial endowment; if b = 0 all the weight is on person 2's utility instead of person 1's, and so the optimization identifies the efficient point on the other edge of the lens. As b varies smoothly between these two extremes, all the in-between points on the contract curve are traced out.

Note that the above optimizations are not ones that the two people would actually engage in, either explicitly or implicitly. Instead, these optimizations are simply a way for the economist to identify points on the contract curve.

See also

References

  • Mas-Colell, Andreu; Whinston, Michael D.; & Green, Jerry (1995). Microeconomic Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 0-19-510268-1