Adelic algebraic group: Difference between revisions

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search
en>TakuyaMurata
move up see also
en>Omnipaedista
commented out empty section
 
Line 1: Line 1:
In [[economics]], '''returns to scale''' and '''[[economies of scale]]''' are related terms that describe what happens as the scale of production increases in the long run, when all [[factor of production|input]] levels including physical [[capital (economics)|capital]] usage are variable (chosen by the firm). They are different terms and should not be used interchangeably. The term '''returns to scale''' arises in the context of a firm's [[production function]].  It explains the behaviour of rate of increase in the output/production to the subsequent increase in the inputs i.e. the factors of production in the long run. In the long run all factors of production are variable and subject to change due to a given increase in size/scale.
Oscar is how he's called and he totally loves this title. Years in the past we moved to North Dakota. To collect coins is 1 of the issues I love most. In her expert life she is a payroll clerk but she's always needed her own business.<br><br>my page healthy food delivery ([http://s2p.at/dietdelivery10007 Click On this site])
The laws of Returns to scale is a set of three inter-related and chronological laws (stages):
Law of Increasing Returns to Scale,
Law of Constant Returns to Scale,
and Law of Diminishing returns to Scale.
If output increases by that same proportional change then there are '''constant returns to scale''' (CRS). If output increases by less than that proportional change in inputs, there are '''decreasing returns to scale''' (DRS). If output increases by more than that proportional change in inputs, there are '''increasing returns to scale''' (IRS).  In mainstream microeconomics, the returns to scale faced by a firm are purely technologically imposed and are not influenced by economic decisions or by market conditions (i.e., conclusions about returns to scale are derived from the specific mathematical structure of the production function ''in isolation'').
 
A firm's production function could exhibit different types of returns to scale in different ranges of output.  Typically, there could be increasing returns at relatively low output levels, decreasing returns at relatively high output levels, and constant returns at one output level between those ranges.{{Citation needed|date=January 2012}}
 
==Example==
 
When all inputs increase by a factor of 2, new values for output will be:
 
* Twice the previous output if there are constant returns to scale (CRS)
 
* Less than twice the previous output if there are decreasing returns to scale (DRS)
 
* More than twice the previous output if there are increasing returns to scale (IRS)
 
Assuming that the factor costs are constant (that is, that the firm is a perfect competitor in all input markets), a firm experiencing constant returns will have constant [[cost curve|long-run average costs]], a firm experiencing decreasing returns will have increasing long-run average costs, and a firm experiencing increasing returns will have decreasing long-run average costs.<ref>{{cite journal |last=Gelles |first=Gregory M. |last2=Mitchell |first2=Douglas W. |title=Returns to scale and economies of scale: Further observations |journal=[[Journal of Economic Education]] |volume=27 |year=1996 |issue=3 |pages=259–261 |jstor=1183297 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Frisch |first=R. |title=Theory of Production |location=Dordrecht |publisher=D. Reidel |year=1965 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Ferguson |first=C. E. |title=The Neoclassical Theory of Production and Distribution |location=London |publisher=Cambridge University Press |year=1969 |isbn=0-521-07453-3 }}</ref>  However, this relationship breaks down if the firm does not face perfectly competitive factor markets (i.e., in this context, the price one pays for a good does depend on the amount purchased). For example, if there are increasing returns to scale in some range of output levels, but the firm is so big in one or more input markets that increasing its purchases of an input drives up the input's per-unit cost, then the firm could have diseconomies of scale in that range of output levels. Conversely, if the firm is able to get bulk discounts of an input, then it could have economies of scale in some range of output levels even if it has decreasing returns in production in that output range.
 
==Network effect==
 
[[Network effect|Network externalities]]  resemble economies of scale, but they are not considered such because they are a function of the number of users of a good or service in an industry, not of the production efficiency within a business. Economies of scale external to the firm (or industry-wide scale economies) are only considered examples of network externalities if they are driven by demand.
 
==Formal definitions==
 
Formally, a production function <math>\ F(K,L)</math> is defined to have:
*Constant returns to scale if (for any constant ''a''  greater than 0) <math>\ F(aK,aL)=aF(K,L) </math>
*Increasing returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' greater than 1) <math>\ F(aK,aL)>aF(K,L), </math>
*Decreasing returns to scale if (for any constant ''a'' smaller than 1) <math>\ F(aK,aL)<aF(K,L) </math>
where ''K'' and ''L'' are factors of production—capital and labor, respectively.
 
==Formal example==
 
The [[Cobb-Douglas]] functional form has constant returns to scale when the sum of the exponents adds up to one.
The function is:
:<math>\ F(K,L)=AK^{b}L^{1-b}</math>
where <math>A > 0</math> and <math>0 < b < 1</math>.  Thus
:<math>\ F(aK,aL)=A(aK)^{b}(aL)^{1-b}=Aa^{b}a^{1-b}K^{b}L^{1-b}=aAK^{b}L^{1-b}=aF(K,L).</math>
 
But if the Cobb-Douglas production function has its general form
 
:<math>\ F(K,L)=AK^{b}L^{c}</math>
 
with <math>0<c<1,</math> then there are increasing returns if ''b'' + ''c'' > 1 but decreasing returns if ''b'' + ''c'' < 1, since
 
:<math>\ F(aK,aL)=A(aK)^{b}(aL)^{c}=Aa^{b}a^{c}K^{b}L^{c}=a^{b+c}AK^{b}L^{c}=a^{b+c}F(K,L),</math>
 
which is greater than or less than <math>aF(K,L)</math> as ''b''+''c'' is greater or less than one.
 
==See also==
{{Portal|Economics}}
*[[Diseconomies of scale]]
*[[Economies of agglomeration]]
*[[Economies of scope]]
*[[Experience curve effects]]
*[[Ideal firm size]]
*[[Homogeneous function]]
*[[Mohring effect]]
*[[Moore's law]]
 
==References==
{{reflist}}
 
==Further reading==
* Susanto Basu (2008). "returns to scale measurement," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'', 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_I000297&edition=current&q=Increasing%20Returns&topicid=&result_number=5 Abstract.]
* [[James M. Buchanan]] and Yong J. Yoon, ed. (1994) ''The Return to Increasing Returns''. U.Mich. Press. Chapter-preview [http://books.google.com/books?id=d4yFu-yVn1AC&printsec=find&pg=PR5=false#v=onepage&q&f=false links.]
* John Eatwell (1987). "returns to scale," ''[[The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics]]'', v. 4, pp.&nbsp;165–66.
* Joaquim Silvestre (1987). "economies and diseconomies of scale," ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp.&nbsp;80–84.
* Spirros Vassilakis (1987). "increasing returns to scale,"  ''The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics'', v. 2, pp.&nbsp;761–64.
 
==External links==
* [http://internationalecon.com/v1.0/ch80/80c020.html Economies of Scale and Returns to Scale]
* [https://www.youtube.com/watch?v=AttvGU47Eg8 Video Lecture on Returns to Scale in Macroeconomics]
 
{{microeconomics}}
 
[[Category:Microeconomics]]
[[Category:Production economics]]

Latest revision as of 07:54, 26 December 2014

Oscar is how he's called and he totally loves this title. Years in the past we moved to North Dakota. To collect coins is 1 of the issues I love most. In her expert life she is a payroll clerk but she's always needed her own business.

my page healthy food delivery (Click On this site)