16S rRNA (cytidine1402-2'-O)-methyltransferase

From formulasearchengine
Jump to navigation Jump to search

In game theory, an aggregative game is a game in which every player’s payoff is a function of the player’s own strategy and the aggregate of all players’ strategies. The concept was first proposed by Nobel laureate Reinhard Selten in 1970 who considered the case where the aggregate is the sum of the players' strategies.

Definition

Consider a standard non-cooperative game with n players, where Si is the strategy set of player i, S=S1×S2××Sn is the joint strategy set, and fi:S is the payoff function of player i. The game is then called an aggregative game if for each player i there exists a function f~i:Si× such that for all sS:

fi(s)=f~i(si,j=1nsj)

In words, payoff functions in aggregative games depend on players' own strategies and the aggregate sj. As an example, consider the Cournot model where firm i has payoff/profit function fi(s)=siP(sj)Ci(si) (here P and Ci are, respectively, the inverse demand function and the cost function of firm i). This is an aggregative game since fi(s)=f~i(si,sj) where f~i(si,X)=siP(X)Ci(si).

Generalizations

A number of generalizations of the standard definition of an aggregative game have appeared in the literature. A game is generalized aggregative[1] if there exists an additively separable function g:S (i.e., if there exist increasing functions h0,h1,,hn: such that g(s)=h0(ihi(si))) such that for each player i there exists a function f~i:Si× such that fi(s)=f~i(si,g(s1,,sn)) for all sS. Obviously, any aggregative game is generalized aggregative as seen by taking g(s1,,sn)=gi. A more general definition still is that of quasi-aggregative games where agents' payoff functions are allowed to depend on different functions of opponents' strategies.[2] Aggregative games can also be generalized to allow for infinitely many players in which case the aggregator will typically be an integral rather than a linear sum.[3] Aggregative games with a continuum of players are frequently studied in mean field game theory.

Properties

  • Generalized aggregative games (hence aggregative games) admit backward reply correspondences and in fact, is the most general class to do so.[1] Backward reply correspondences, as well as the closely related share correspondences, are powerful analytical tools in game theory. For example, backward reply correspondences were used to give the first general proof of the existence of a Nash equilibrium in the Cournot model without assuming quasiconcavity of firms' profit functions.[4] Backward reply correspondences also play a crucial role for comparative statics analysis (see below).
  • Quasi-aggregative games (hence generalized aggregative games, hence aggregative games) are best-response potential games if best-response correspondences are either increasing or decreasing.[5][2] Precisely as games with strategic complementarities, such games therefore have a pure strategy Nash equilibrium regardless of whether payoff functions are quasiconcave and/or strategy sets are convex. The existence proof in [4] is a special case of such more general existence results.
  • Aggregative games have strong comparative statics properties. Under very general conditions one can predict how a change in exogenous parameters will affect the Nash equilibria.[6][7]

See also

Notes

43 year old Petroleum Engineer Harry from Deep River, usually spends time with hobbies and interests like renting movies, property developers in singapore new condominium and vehicle racing. Constantly enjoys going to destinations like Camino Real de Tierra Adentro.

References

  • 20 year-old Real Estate Agent Rusty from Saint-Paul, has hobbies and interests which includes monopoly, property developers in singapore and poker. Will soon undertake a contiki trip that may include going to the Lower Valley of the Omo.

    My blog: http://www.primaboinca.com/view_profile.php?userid=5889534